Coordinating for Quality and Organization: A Theoretical Model and Empirical Findings

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Coordinating for Quality and Organization: A Theoretical Model and Empirical Findings"

Transcription

1 Coordinating for Quality and Organization: A Theoretical Model and Empirical Findings Guenter Schamel Associate Professor School of Economics and Management Free University of Bozen-Bolzano Bozen-Bolzano, BZ, 39100, ITALY Telephone: Fax: guenter.schamel@unibz.it Francisco Javier Santos-Arteaga Research Associate School of Economics and Management Free University of Bozen-Bolzano Bozen-Bolzano, BZ, 39100, ITALY FranciscoJavier.Santos-Arteaga@unibz.it Presented at the Economics and Management of Networks Conference (EMNet 2013) ( Robinson Hotel and University Ibn Zohr Agadir, Morocco November 21-23,

2 Coordinating for Quality and Organization: A Theoretical Model and Empirical Findings Abstract The theoretical section of the paper presents a formal model illustrating how cooperatives and private firms can coexist within a market while obtaining different quality rewards. The basic intuition follows from the literature on firm boundaries determined via incomplete contracts where organizational forms, when agreed upon competitively, condition the sense of entitlement of the parties. If feeling aggrieved by the outcome of the contract, parties may shade by underperforming, which creates deadweight losses. The main result obtained states that if the intensity of shading depends positively on the existing payoff imbalances between bosses and managers, then (non)integration with coordination is more plausible when the profits of bosses and benefits of managers are (dis)similar. Moreover, given some plausible parameter constraints, social surplus tends to be higher under integration whenever coordination takes place. These results illustrate that both organizational forms, an integrated cooperative and a nonintegrated private firm, may coexist in a coordinated equilibrium and how the former may even obtain a higher social surplus than the latter one. When applied to our empirical setting, this result leads us to conclude that similar interests between both parties, the boss and the unit managers, strengthened by the shared regional DOC denomination, would lead to a small value of shading, which encourages coordination within a cooperative (integrated) environment. On the other hand, privately emphasizing a dominant brand over the rest obtaining an IGT denomination premium results from dissimilar interests between the parties, which leads to a nonintegrated though coordinated equilibrium scenario. In the empirical section we analyze a data set for cooperative and private wineries from Northern Italy (Alto Adige and Trentino). We first use a hedonic model to test whether wines from private wineries receive a wine quality premium and/or a reputation premium for ownership structure relative to cooperatives. For Alto Adige, we estimate a significantly positive reputation premium and a higher quality premium for wines produced by cooperatives. For the Trentino, we estimate a significant reputation premium for private wineries but higher quality premium for wines produced by cooperatives. In a second model, we include interaction terms between quality denominations (IGT/DOC) and organizational form (i.e. Coop/Non-Coop) to see if there is any strategic orientation towards specific denomination rules and organizational forms. Our expected result is that cooperatives concentrate on regional DOC rules while private wineries increasingly turn to a strategy of marketing and branding distinctly different IGT wines. We test this hypothesis estimating a modified equation on the whole sample with DOC wines produced by cooperatives selected as base category wines. The estimated coefficients indicate that cooperatives may emphasize DOC production and use IGT denomination for lower quality grapes, while private producers tend to use IGT to market distinctly different wines often with specific brand names. 2

3 Introduction Privately owned firms and cooperatives represent ownership forms that can be found concurrently in many markets throughout the world (Sexton and Lavoie, 2001; Van Bekkum and van Dijk, 1997). Even in the U.S., cooperative enterprises are predominant in a number of industries including agriculture where they market as much as 1/3 of total production (Hansmann, 1996). Also in Europe, large share of agricultural produce is marketed by farmer-owned cooperatives, but increasingly concerns are raised about their effectiveness and efficiency. In Europe, recent changes of the common agricultural policy imply that production and marketing of these products must meet specific requirements (improved quality management and marketing conditions, production efficiency etc.) in order to comply with internal support regulations and to attain competitive positions within Europe as well as internationally. We propose a model of product quality and reputation of cooperatives versus privately owned firms and how they are reflected in market prices. As an application, we examine the wine sector in the province of Alto Adige in Northern Italy where about 70% of the total wine production is marketed through cooperatives. For comparison, this is more than twice as much as in Germany where about 1/3 of the total production is processed and marketed by cooperatives (DRV, 2009). Product quality and reputation crucially affect product prices. Depending on the producer, considerable price differences exist even between similar products. In the case of wine, we often observe that a bottle produced and marketed by a cooperative sells for less than a bottle of comparable quality from a privately owned firm. One explanation for this may be that cooperatives lack control over the entire production chain which can lead to larger variation in grape quality and hence higher uncertainty about wine quality further downstream. Thus, consumers face uncertainties regarding product quality and reputation for cooperatively produced wine. A cooperative s reputation for product quality depends on the contributions of individual members growing grapes subject to variation as well as on the cooperative management ability to produce high quality wine. In contrast, a privately owned firm can be characterized by a higher degree of control within the production chain and thus may also be able to gain higher levels of reputation. In Alto Adige, wine cooperatives are characterized by modern production conditions and utilization of cutting-edge vineyard management systems. For example, they require that growers are cutting back on grape tonnage at certain predefined times during the growing season in order to limit yields, thus raising grape quality and wine quality further down the production line. (Schamel and Schubert, 2012). Therefore, it would be interesting to see if the cooperatives are able to claim sufficient control of the production chain relative to non-cooperative producers such that the hypothesized difference in the wine quality and reputation premium disappears. While the focus in this paper is on vertical collaboration between growers and winemaking within a cooperative enterprise, inter-organizational (i.e. horizontal) collaboration has been identified as an important success factor for the Australian wine industry (Jordan, Zidda and Lockshin, 2007). Theoretical Environment This section of the paper presents a formal model illustrating how cooperatives and private firms can coexist within a market while obtaining different quality rewards. We build on the model developed by Hart and Holmstrom (2010) to analyze the strategic choice of organizational form among producers. We will particularly concentrate on the similarity of the payoffs received by the parties composing the units within an organization as the main determinant of the boundary 3

4 choices of firms. Payoff similarities will also be used to show how cooperatives may be more socially efficient than private producers within the current strategic setting. Basic Assumptions and Notation The basic environment is that of Hart and Holmstrom (2010) and we will therefore restate their initial assumptions and maintain their notation. The basic intuition follows from the literature on firm boundaries determined via incomplete contracts where organizational forms, when agreed upon competitively, condition the sense of entitlement of the parties. If feeling aggrieved by the outcome of the contract, parties may shade by underperforming, which creates deadweight losses. If ever at all, shading takes place after the organizational form has been chosen. The strategic environment is composed by two units, A and B, that have a lateral relationship, i.e. they interact within the same output or input market, such that each unit is operated by a manager who triggers external effects on the other unit. Units are presented with a binary decision, they must choose either Yes or No. Coordination occurs if and only if both units choose Yes. Otherwise, units face noncoordination. In this sense, coordination may be interpreted as the decision of both units to remain as active producers within a joint project while any of them leaving the project results in noncoordination. Two main organizational forms are considered: nonintegration, where units are separate firms whose managers are also the bosses, and integration, where units are part of a single firm with an outside manager acting as the boss and the managers of each unit as subordinates. We will identify nonintegrated organizational forms with private independent firms, while the integrated scenario will be assumed to correspond to a cooperative structure. Intuitively, one can consider wineries as being composed by growers and winemakers. Growers could delegate the winemaking process in an external winemaker or contribute to the winemaking process themselves. When growers delegate in an external manager [integration], their individual contributions to the process are not explicitly acknowledged, with the winemaker losing complete control over the quality of the production chain. However, if growers interact in the winemaking process themselves [nonintegration], they are able to highlight the quality of their individual contributions within the production chain. In this regard, a higher degree of quality control is exerted over the production chain. Two types of benefits are assumed to be generated by each unit: monetary transferable profits, v i, i = A, B, and private nontransferable benefits, w i, i = A, B, in the form of job satisfaction for the manager working in the corresponding unit. The boss of a unit can divert all profits from the unit to herself, leading to a nonintegrated payoff of v i + w i if she is also the manager of unit i = A, B. Private benefits always reside with the managers. Thus, if both units are integrated, the professional outsider acting as boss receives v A + v B. Note that, under nonintegration both bosses account for the private benefits generated by each unit, which are ignored under integration in favor of total profits. Social surplus is given in both cases by v A + v B + w A + w B. Given the previous setting, bosses and unit managers face the following coordination game Payoffs Yes No Yes (Δv A, Δw A ); (Δv B, Δw B ) (0, 0); (0, 0) No (0, 0); (0, 0) (0, 0); (0, 0) 4

5 where the row payoffs correspond to unit A and the column ones to unit B. Without loss of generality, profits and private benefits have been normalized to zero in both units under noncoordination. The following notation is introduced to simplify the presentation Δz A = Δv A + Δw A, Δz B = Δv B + Δw B. where Δz i, i = A, B, represents the change in total surplus in unit i derived from coordination, and Δz A + Δz B accounts for the change in aggregate social surplus absent shading costs. Henceforth, S will denote the social surplus obtained net of shading costs. Coordination is assumed to lead to a reduction in private benefits due to the independence lost by the managers and its effect on job satisfaction Δw A 0, Δw B 0. Shading will be used to force bosses to internalize the externalities generated on other parties. This may occur under integration and nonintegration, since the relationship between both units is assumed to persist in both settings after the strategic coordination decision is made. It will also be assumed that a party receiving k i less than his maximum payoff will be aggrieved by k i and shade to the point where the payoff received by the other party falls by θk i. Hart and Holmstrom assume that θ ϵ (0,1) is an exogenous parameter identical for all parties. We will endogenize this parameter as a function of the spread existing between coordination profits and private benefits within a given unit. Moreover, our results will require the upper bound of the image interval on which θ is defined to be widen. We will elaborate further on the intuition lying behind the results obtained in the following section. The non-integration coordination condition (NIC) defined for any Δz i value, i = A, B, is given by Δz i + θ Δz j 0, (1) where i j. If Δz i 0, i = A, B, then (1) is trivially satisfied. However, if Δz i < 0, and Δz j > 0, then this condition states that coordination will take place under non-integration only if the costs of shading imposed by manager j on manager i are larger than the losses derived by the latter from coordination. Social surplus in the (NIC) setting [with Δz i < 0, and Δz j > 0 ] is therefore given by S NIC = Δz A + Δz B + θδz i under coordination - θδz j under noncoordination Note that, if coordination occurs, then unit i will shade by θδz i, as it receives a payoff of Δz i < 0 from coordinating. The integration coordination condition (INT) defined for any Δv i value, i = A, B, is given by Δv i + Δv j +θ(δw i + Δw j ) 0. (2) Trivially, if Δv i 0, i = A, B, then (2) is violated. Thus, for this condition to hold we need at least one of the Δv i changes in private profits to be positive. 5

6 Social surplus in the (INT) setting [with Δz i < 0, Δz j > 0, and Δv i + Δv j > 0] is given by S INT = Δz A + Δz B + θ(δw A + Δw B ) under coordination - θ(δv A + Δv B ) under noncoordination If coordination takes place, then managers will shade by θ(δw A + Δw B ), as both Δw A and Δw B are negative. If, on the other hand, condition (2) does not hold and units do not coordinate, then the boss will shade by θ(δv A + Δv B ). In order to provide additional intuition for the analysis performed in the next section, we rewrite the respective (NIC) and (INT) coordination conditions as follows Δv A + Δw A + θ (Δv B + Δw B ) 0 (1 ) Δv A + θδw A + Δv B + θδw B 0 (2 ) It should be noted that the lower degree of quality control exerted over the production chain within the cooperative [integrated] environment implies that the contributions of the individual growers to the winemaking process cannot be explicitly acknowledged. As a result, when shading, they can only do so through their respective Δw A and Δw B values, as illustrated in equation (2 ). On the other hand, private [nonintegrated] wineries are able to recognize the contributions of the individual growers, which allows the latter ones to shade through their entire Δz B values, as described by equation (1 ). Main Results Intuitive Presentation The organizational form is chosen so as to maximize social surplus net of shading costs, which may be incurred after a given organizational form has been agreed upon. In this regard, units may either operate independently or delegate in an independent boss who maximizes her joint private profit. We start by illustrating how, given our definition of shading intensity, managers will be more willing to delegate if their Δw values are close to the respective Δv of the boss. Consider the coordination payoffs received by the managers and the boss within each unit. We endogenize the intensity of the shading parameter θ as a function of the difference in coordination incentives existing between the boss and the unit managers. The definition of the [finite] θ i (v, w) variable, i = A, B, is therefore given by θ i (Δv i, Δw i ) = Δv i + Δw i (3) Note that we have to account for the possibility that Δv i < 0, while knowing that Δw i < 0 under coordination. Thus, a substantial difference between both payoffs leads to an increase in the value of the shading parameter. That is, the strength or effort dedicated by a party to shade depends on the existing differences in objectives (and payoffs) with respect to the other one. This assumption follows directly from the guilt-envy (Fehr-Schmidt) inequality aversion literature based on comparisons of absolute differences in payoffs between the parties, see Camerer (2003) for a review of the literature on this topic. The importance that the shading parameter has in determining the coordination incentives of bosses and managers within both units can be easily illustrated numerically. Coordination Incentives with θ = 0. 6

7 INT > NIC always in the setting with Δz i < 0, and Δz j > 0, even if coordination does not take place, since Δv A + Δw A 0, (1 ) Δv A + Δv B 0, (2 ) and Δv B > 0 while Δw A < 0. Coordination Incentives with θ = 0.5, Δv A = Δv B = 5, and Δw A, Δw B ϵ [-10, 0]. Coordination Incentives with θ = 1. INT = NIC. It is easy to see how coordination is more likely to take place under integration (nonintegration) when the θ variable is relatively low (high). In this case, similar (dissimilar) interests between both parties in the form of coordination payoffs would lead to a lower (higher) shading intensity, which encourages coordination within an integrated (nonintegrated) organizational environment. 1 It immediately follows that Lemma 1. If the intensity of shading depends positively on the existing payoff imbalances between bosses and managers, we have the following 1 It should be noted that θ i (Δv i, Δw i ) could be normalized within the [0, 1] interval after defining (exogenously) some bounds for Δv and Δw. This constraint would keep the analysis within the parameter value limits considered by Hart and Holmstrom, where (1) (2). However, if θ is allowed to be defined above one, as is the case here, then we have that (2) (1) for θ > 1. In this regard, when comparing absolute differences in payoffs between both parties, we could also define ex-ante bounds for Δv and Δw determining a pair of θ i (Δv i, Δw i ), i = A, B, integration limit values. The analysis performed in the following section provides additional intuition on this option. 7

8 Integration with coordination is more plausible when the profits of bosses and benefits of managers are similar. Nonintegration with coordination is more plausible when the profits of bosses and benefits of managers are dissimilar. Corollary 1. Given Δz i < 0, Δz j > 0, and Δv i < 0, social surplus tends to be higher under integration whenever coordination takes place, due partly to the lower θ values generated by the respective units. Both these previous results are merely intuitive and the intuition justifying them follows from basic numerical examples. However, these results illustrate that both organizational forms, an integrated cooperative and a nonintegrated private firm, may coexist in a coordinated equilibrium and how the former may even obtain a higher social surplus than the latter one. Formal Analysis We turn now to a more formal analysis where the current model will be used to explain how both these organizational forms may coexist optimally within unequal coordinated equilibria. Cooperatives are more willing coordinate when the θ (Δv, Δw) values are small and similar for all units involved. At the same time, if heterogeneity is allowed for in the values of θ (Δv, Δw), then any unit with a sufficiently divergent payoff structure [leading to a high θ (Δv, Δw) value] has an incentive to avoid the integrated setting and impose a nonintegrated though coordinated organizational form. Thus, highly unequal θ (Δv, Δw) values between units favor the emergence of nonintegrated but coordinated structures. 2 In order to illustrate these points, we must allow for heterogeneous θ (Δv, Δw) values to be defined between both units. Consider two different θ i (Δv i, Δw i ) values, θ A and θ B, one for each unit, though the analysis can easily account for a larger number of units. We concentrate on the nontrivial Δz i < 0, and Δz j > 0 case, and assume that i=a and j=b. Thus, in order for a nonintegrated equilibrium with coordination to be more plausible than an integrated equilibrium with coordination we need (1 ) > (2 ), which, after some basic algebra, implies that (1 θ A ) Δw A > (1 θ B ) Δv B. (4) Note that Δw A < 0 and Δv B > 0. As a result, it is sufficient (though not necessary) for this inequality to hold that either θ A or θ B are higher than one with the other being at least as high. This implies that large payoff differentials between both parties within a unit may shift coordination to a nonintegrated environment. However, it is also possible for this inequality to hold when θ B > 1 and θ A < 1. In this case, the unit shifting faces larger payoff inequalities between its parties. Moreover, Δv B should be large enough to achieve coordination under nonintegration, an equilibrium which would not necessarily be plausible under integration. Clearly, for the sake of completeness, an integrated equilibrium with coordination would be more plausible than a nonintegrated equilibrium with coordination if (2 ) > (1 ), which implies that (1 θ B ) Δv B > (1 θ A ) Δw A. (4 ) 2 It clearly follows that a larger number of heterogeneous units would favor the nonintegrated [coordinated] setting over integration. 8

9 In this case, it is sufficient (though not necessary) for this inequality to hold that either θ B < 1 and θ A 1 or θ B 1 and θ A < 1. Social surplus could be higher under either one of these organizational structures. Note, however, that highly aligned and similar payoffs work in favor of an integrated organization [cooperative] due to the smaller value of θ generated by its units. We will show how, in the Δz i < 0, and Δz j > 0 case, there exist reasonable payoff and shading values that allow for an integrated organizational form to lead to a higher social surplus under coordination than the nonintegrated one. For this to be the case, we require that S INT > S NIC under coordination which simplifies to Δz A + Δz B + θ A Δw A + θ B Δw B > Δz A + Δz B + θ A Δz A θ B Δw B > θ A Δv A. (5) We know from equation (4) that θ B > θ A. 3 Thus, in order for (5) to hold we need 0 > Δw B >> Δv A. The main implications derived from equations (4) and (5) for the coexistence of both organizational forms within socially unequal coordinated equilibria are summarized as follows Δv B >> 0 Δw B >> Δv A Δw A. (6) These requirements state that the unit avoiding integration must exhibit considerably unequal payoffs between the boss and the manager. In this case, the unit avoids integration but keeps on coordinating under nonintegration. At the same time, the other unit must exhibit similar negative payoffs that prevent its shading from affecting coordination under integration. 4 Clearly, in order for coordination under integration to be more plausible and lead to a higher social surplus than coordination under nonintegration we simply require that Δv B > 0 Δw B > Δv A Δw A, which is implied by (6). Regarding our empirical setting, described through the following sections, we may conclude that similar interests between both parties, the boss and the unit managers, strengthened by the shared DOC denomination, would lead to a small value of θ, which encourages coordination within a cooperative [integrated] environment. On the other hand, privately emphasizing a dominant brand over the rest in order to obtain an IGT denomination premium results from dissimilar interests between the parties, which leads to a nonintegrated but coordinated equilibrium scenario. 3 Note that it is also possible for both θ values to be higher than one with θ B θ A, which would weaken the strength of the requirements derived from equation (5). 4 Note that Δz A < 0 is an essential requirement for social surplus to be higher under integration. If this were not the case and Δv A > 0, then social surplus would always be lower under integration since Δw B < 0 < Δv A, which violates (5). Unit A managers shade in both cases due to the benefits lost under coordination, but when Δv A > 0 the boss of the unit obtains positive profits that relatively increase the nonintegrated social surplus despite the intensity of his shading. 9

10 Data and Analysis We analyze a data set of wines evaluated in the annual Le Guide de l Espresso (I vini d Italia) for the Alto Adige and Trentino regions in Northern Italy. We obtained three years of data published in the guide for the years The sample used in the estimation consists of 1265 wines from Alto Adige and 724 from Trentino. We employ a hedonic model to test whether cooperatives or private wineries can obtain higher implicit prices for specific parameters that directly impact welfare levels. A higher level of welfare may be reached through a price premium for the collective reputation indicator for cooperatives as quality wine producers or through a higher wine quality premium. The data guide lists a range of applicable retail prices per bottle from which we use the lower bound for estimation purposes. The price information used in the estimation is submitted prior to the quality evaluation (i.e. the point rating by the expert tasters). Thus, it does not reflect any direct effects due to a favorable quality rating. The experts rate the wines according to a 20-point scale in half-point steps. Information on the number of bottles of a particular wine produced is also provided. The age of the wines when evaluated ranged from 1 to 13 years. Le Guide de l Espresso also provides a starranking (between 0 and 3) for a winery s distinctiveness which could be regarded as a proxy for individual winery reputation. Moreover, the wine guide differentiates wine color, sweet or desert wines, DOC and IGT designated wines, biologically or bio-dynamically produced wine, wine variety and special recommendations such as value for money and best regional buys. In addition, the data set allows to categorize whether a wine was produced by a local cooperative or not. Cooperatively produced wines, red vs. white wines, sweet wines, IGT vs. DOC designated wines, bio-labeled wines and special recommendations are regular dummy variables while wine variety is a categorical dummy. As dependent variable we use the logarithm of the lower price bound [log(p)]. We employ a log-linear function in our estimation. In a first regression, we estimate the following equation without interaction terms (Model 1): log(p) = α + β 1 log(points)+β 2 log(bottles)+β 3 Age +β 4 Stars +γ 1 Red + γ 2 Sweet + γ 3 Coop + γ 4 IGT + γ 5 Bio + γ 6j Variety + θ 1 ValueRec + θ 2 BuyRec + ε where log(p) is the logarithm of price P, log(points) is the logarithm of the Gault Millau points and log(bottles) is the logarithm of the production quantity, Coop is dummy variable as an indicator for the collective reputation of cooperatives while ε is the error term with a zero mean and uniform variance. The regression equation stated above includes a number of variables to control for willingness to pay (price) effects due to: - production quantity (scarcity effect implied by the number of bottles produced) β 2 - wine age (storage premium due to age in years at the time of evaluation) β 3 - star ranking (winery reputation effect) β 4 - red vs. white wines (red wine premium) γ 1 - sweet or dessert wines (sweet wine premium) γ 2 - IGT classification effect (outside DOC rules) γ 4 - Bio-labeled wines (organic-premium) γ 5 - wine variety (varietal premium) γ 6j - value recommendation (ValueRec) θ 1 - best buy recommendation (BuyRec) θ 2. 10

11 Given its log-linear functional form, estimating the equation above yields price premiums and discounts relative to the contribution of the base category (non-sweet white DOC wine that is not bio-labeled and not a differentiated variety for the region). We differentiate seven varieties/wine types in the estimation. Five are in common for both regions (Gewürztraminer, Pinot Noir, Sauvignon Blanc, Riesling and Spumante). Lagrein and Schavia are specific for Alto Adige while Teroldego, Nosiola are specific for Trentino. According to our expectation that consumers face more uncertainty regarding product quality and reputation for cooperatively produced wine, we hypothesize that wines coming from privately owned producers receive a price premium relative to cooperatively produced wine. To test this hypothesis, we employ a hedonic pricing model differentiating cooperative vs. non-cooperative producers. To test the hypothesis that cooperatively produced wines receive a reputation discount relative to other producers, we expect a significant but negative coefficient for the cooperative dummy variable (indicating a negative collective reputation for cooperatives). Thus, we would look for a negative coefficient γ 3 for wine produced by cooperatives. Moreover, if we split the sample into wines produced by cooperatives and private wineries (non-cooperatives) we would expect a lower quality premium for cooperatively produced wines. Using our data set of two different wine regions in Northern Italy, we would also like to test if there are regional differences in terms of quality coordination and ownership structure. Our a priori expectation is that cooperatives in Alto Adige achieve a higher level of quality coordination and thus are in a better position to compete with private wineries in terms of wine quality and reputation. Thus comparing Model 1 results for Alto Adige and Trentino, we would expect that cooperatives in Alto Adige outperform the cooperative in Trentino in terms of reputation and quality premiums. In a second model, we include interaction terms between DOC and IGT denominations and ownership structure (Coop vs. NonCoop) in order to examine if there is any strategic orientation towards specific denomination rules with respect to ownership structures. Our expected result is that cooperatives are concentrating on DOC denominated wines while privately owned wineries are increasingly producing and marketing distinctly different wines outside DOC rules. The second regression equation estimated looks as follows (Model 2): log(p) = α + β 1 log(points)+β 2 log(bottles)+β 3 Age +β 4 Stars +γ 1 Red + γ 2 Sweet + γ 5 Bio + γ 6j Variety + θ 1 ValueRec + θ 2 BuyRec + η 1 IGT*Coop + η 2 IGT*NonCoop + η 3 DOC*NonCoop + ε Notice that in Model 2, the base category is a cooperatively produced DOC wine (a non-sweet white wine that is not bio-labeled and not a differentiated variety in the region). The three remaining interaction terms between denomination rules and ownership structure are: - IGT * Coop or IGT classified wine produced by cooperatives - IGT * NonCoop or IGT classified wine produced by privately owned wineries - DOC * NonCoop or DOC classified wine produced by privately owned wineries Finally, we tested the models and/or the residuals for normality (Jarque-Bera-Test) and heteroskedasticity (White-Test) and do not find any significant problems in the data. We also employed a RESET test which rejected other functional forms. 11

12 Results The results of our estimation for Model 1 are listed in Table 1 (for Alto Adige/AA) and Table 2 (for Trentino/TN). We cannot confirm the hypothesis that wines coming from privately owned producers receive a reputation premium relative to cooperatively produced wines for the Alto Adige region. Our estimation for AA Wines (Table 1) reveals a significant but positive coefficient for cooperative reputation. This would indicate that Alto Adige cooperatives receive a collective reputation premium (about 11%) relative to their local privately owned competitors. This is even more remarkable given the fact that the model corrects for individual winery reputation via the Stars variable. On the contrary, our estimation for TN Wines (Table 2) reveals a significant but negative reputation coefficient for the Trentino cooperatives (with a collective reputation discount of about 6%). --- Insert Tables 1 and 2 here --- Comparing the quality premium (coefficients on the points rating) in the cooperatively produced subsample relative to the non-coop subsample we can also confirm that the posted hypothesis is not correct for both Alto Adige and Trentino, i.e. that cooperatively produced wines receive a significant quality premium relative to non-coop wines (2.748 vs when comparing the respective columns in Table 1). Thus, we can confirm that cooperatives in Alto Adige and Trentino are characterized by modern production conditions, efficient horizontal coordination using cutting-edge vineyard management systems which in the end result in a significant quality premium relative to their local privately owned competitors. Moreover, in Alto Adige, the model also confirms a positive reputation premium for cooperatively produced wines. Thus, our analysis suggests that these cooperatives are able to claim sufficient control of the production chain relative to non-cooperative producers such that the hypothesized difference in the wine quality and reputation premium disappears. In practice, this is due to requiring growers to cut down the grape tonnage at certain predefined times during the growing season in order to limit yields (often way below the DOC maximum), thus raising grape quality and wine quality further down the production line. The remaining results on the control variables listed in Tables 1 and 2 are as expected in terms of sign and magnitude relative to other studies. For example, the storage effect (wine age) is relatively consistent across the subsamples ranging between 9% and 12%. There is a red wine premium for Alto Adige but not for the Trentino region. It is interesting to note that bio-labeled wine has a positive coefficient at least for Alto Adige which is in contrast to other studies that have claimed the opposite (e.g. Delmas and Grant, 2010). Moreover, we note that the premium on IGT wine is positive for both Alto Adige (10.5%) and Trentino (7.6%). This result suggests that wines produced outside the local DOC rules receive a price premium. Thus, the question is raised whether DOC regulations, established to guarantee quality wine production are not necessarily working in favor of receiving higher market prices. However, we notice that the coefficients for IGT wines are positive and significant in the noncooperative sub-samples for both regions. This would indicate that private wineries may emphasize production according to IGT classification to sell of higher quality grapes and to market own-branded wines while avoiding DOC rules. We argue that this strategic orientation is confirmed by our results. Cooperatives get a collective reputation premium for focusing on DOC rules while their non-cooperative competitors use an IGT strategy emphasizing branding. 12

13 Finally, in Table 3 we list the results including the interaction terms between IGT/DOC denominations and ownership structure (Coop/Non-Coop) for both Alto Adige and Trentino. Comparing IGT and DOC denominations, the estimated coefficients indicate that relative to a cooperatively produced DOC wine, private wineries receive a significant premium for their DOC wines in Trentino (+4.5%) but not so in Alto Adige (-11.3%). Moreover, in Trentino, privately owned wineries receive a significant premium for their IGT wine (relative to cooperatively produced DOC wine) while the coefficient is not significant for Alto Adige. The interaction term for IGT*Coop is not significant for both regions. --- Insert Table 3 here --- The results obtained with both Models corroborate our results obtained in our theoretical model. Cooperatives seem to outperform private wineries in Alto Adige in terms of wine quality and reputation. They do this by emphasizing DOC production and using IGT rules to market lower quality grapes. In Trentino, cooperatives are less successful and private wineries outperform them under DOC rules as well as through IGT when marketing distinctly different wines under specific brand names. In Alto Adige, cooperatives get a collective reputation premium focusing on DOC rules. In Trentino, cooperatives receive lower prices relative to private wineries who manage to receive a price premium of 4.5% for their DOC wines and 13.3% for their IGT wines (relative to a cooperatively produced DOC wine). In Alto Adige, it seems that cooperatives focus on DOC wines while private wineries at least to some degree void DOC rules to market and brand distinctly different IGT wines but according to our sample do not receive a price premium relative to DOC wine. On the other hand, in Trentino, private wineries receive price premia for DOC and IGT wines relative to their cooperative competitors. Summary and Conclusion In this paper, we have introduced a formal model and empirical evidence illustrating how cooperatives and private firms can coexist within a market while obtaining different quality rewards. The reputation of a cooperative for product quality depends on the contributions of its individual growers and its managerial ability to produce high quality wine. In contrast, a privately owned firm is characterized by a higher degree of control within the production chain. Therefore, the choice between a cooperative and a private firm organizational form depends on the difference between the objectives and payoffs obtained by the parties composing the organization and the resulting shading parameters. In Alto Adige, cooperative wineries manage to organize their production decisions such that they are able to compete with private wineries in terms of wine quality and reputation. This empirical result supports the theoretical model that cooperatives may reach a higher social surplus due to larger reputation and quality premiums. 13

14 Table 1: Model 1 Results for Alto Adige/AA (Dependent Variable: Log(Price) AA Wines AA Coops AA Non-Coops Variable Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Constant Log(Points) Log(Bottles) Age Stars Red Wine Sweet Wine Cooperatives IGT Wine Bio-Wine 0.062* * Lagrein Schiava Gewürztraminer Pinot Nero Sauvignon Blanc Riesling Spumante 0.139* * Value for Money Best Buy Region F-statistic Wald F-statistic Adjusted R Std. err. estimate Sum sq. residuals Observations Notes: Estimation Method: LS / White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors & covariance. The symbols,, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. 14

15 Table 2: Model 1 Results for Trentino/TN (Dependent Variable: Log(Price) TN Wines TN Coops TN Non-Coops Variable Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Constant Log(Points) Log(Bottles) Age Stars Red Wine Sweet Wine Cooperatives IGT Wine Bio-Wine Teroldego Schiava * Gewürztraminer Pinot Nero Sauvignon Blanc Riesling Spumante Value for Money Best Buy Region F-statistic Wald F-statistic Adjusted R Std. err. estimate Sum sq. residuals Observations Notes: Estimation Method: LS / White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors & covariance. The symbols,, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. 15

16 Table 3: Model 2 Results for Alto Adige and Trentino (Dependent Variable: Log(Price) Alto Adige Wines Trentino Wines Variable Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Variable Coeff. t-stat. Prob. Constant Constant Log(Points) Log(Points) Log(Bottles) Log(Bottles) Age Age Stars Stars Red Wine Red Wine Sweet Wine Sweet Wine IGT*NonCoop IGT*NonCoop IGT*Coop IGT*Coop DOC*NonCoop DOC*NonCoop 0.045* Bio-Wine 0.064* Bio-Wines Lagrein Teroldego Schavia Nosiola Gewürztraminer Gewürztraminer Pinot Nero Pinot Nero Sauvignon Blanc Sauvignon Blanc Riesling Riesling Spumante 0.136* Spumante Value for Money Value for Money Best Buy Region Best Buy Region F-statistic F-statistic Wald F-statistic Wald F-statistic Adjusted R Adjusted R Std. err. estimate Std. err. estimate Sum sq. resid Sum sq. residuals Observations 1265 Observations 724 Notes: Estimation Method: LS / White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors & covariance. The symbols,, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. 16

17 References BEVERLAND, M. 2007, "Can cooperatives brand? Exploring the interplay between cooperative structure and sustained brand marketing success," Food Policy 32: BONUS, H. 1986, "The Cooperative Association as a Business Enterprise: A Study in the Economics of Transactions," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 142(2): CAMERER, C.F., 2003, Behavioral Game Theory. Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton University Press. DELMAS, M. and GRANT, L., 2010, "Eco-Labeling Strategies and Price-Premium: The Wine Industry Puzzle," Business and Society 49(4): pp DRV, 2008, "Entwicklung der Winzergenossenschaften." Available at FUJITA, M., KRUGMAN, P., and VENABLES, A., 1999, The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. GCAC, 2000, The agricultural cooperation in the European Union: Tendencies and current issues. Brussels: General Committee for Agricultural Cooperation. HANSMANN, H., 1996, The Ownership of Enterprise. Belknap Harvard. HART, O. and HOLMSTROM, B., 2010, A Theory of Firm Scope, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CXXV: pp HELPMAN, E. and KRUGMAN, P., 1985, Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. HOFFMANN R., 2005, Ownership Structure and Endogenous Quality Choice: Cooperatives versus Investor-Owned Firms, Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, 3(2), Article 8. Available at JORDAN, R., ZIDDA, P.; and LOCKSHIN, L., "Behind the Australian wine industry's success: does environment matter?", International Journal of Wine Business Research, Vol. 19 (1), pp ROSEN, S., 1974, Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82: pp SAN MARTIN, G.; TRONCOSO, J., and BRÜMMER, B., 2008, Determinants of Argentinian Wine Prices in the U.S., Journal of Wine Economics, 3 (1), SCHAMEL, G., 2009, "Can German Wine Cooperatives Compete on Quality?" Paper presented at the 27 th International Association of Agricultural Economists Conference, Beijing, China. SCHAMEL, G., and SCHUBERT, S.F. (2012). "A Dynamic Optimal Control Model of Crop Thinning." Paper presented at the 2012 Conference of the International Association of Agricultural Economists in Foz do Iguacu, Brazil. SEXTON, R. J., and LAVOIE, N., 2001, Food Processing and Distribution: An Industrial Organization Approach. (Chapter 15, Volume 1B) in Handbook of Agricultural Economics, edited by Gardner B. and G. Rausser, Elsevier, North Holland, SHAPIRO, C., 1983, "Premiums for high quality products as Returns to reputations," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98: TIROLE, J., 1988, The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. TIROLE, J., "A theory of collective reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to firm quality)," Review of Economic Studies, 63: VAN BEKKUM, O., and VAN DIJK, G., 1997, Agricultural Cooperatives in the European Union, Trends and Issues of the 21st Century. Assen: van Gorcum. 17

Coordinating for Quality: How Cooperatives can beat Private Wineries on Quality and Reputation

Coordinating for Quality: How Cooperatives can beat Private Wineries on Quality and Reputation Coordinating for Quality: How Cooperatives can beat Private Wineries on Quality and Reputation Guenter Schamel Free University of Bozen-Bolzano guenter.schamel@unibz.it Purpose: We address if cooperatives

More information

Wine quality, reputation, denominations: How cooperatives and private wineries compete?

Wine quality, reputation, denominations: How cooperatives and private wineries compete? BIO Web of Conferences 3, 03008 (2014) DOI: 10.1051/bioconf/20140303008 c Owned by the authors, published by EDP Sciences, 2014 Wine quality, reputation, denominations: How cooperatives and private wineries

More information

Firm Organizational and Payoff Imbalances: An Aggrievement Model with Cooperatives and Private Firms

Firm Organizational and Payoff Imbalances: An Aggrievement Model with Cooperatives and Private Firms Firm Organizational and Payoff Imbalances: An Aggrievement Model with Cooperatives and Private Firms Guenter H. Schamel guenter.schamel@unibz.it and Francisco J. Santos-Arteaga FranciscoJavier.Santos-Arteaga@unibz.it

More information

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries Patrizia FANASCH

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries Patrizia FANASCH Padua 2017 Abstract Submission I want to submit an abstract for: Conference Presentation Corresponding Author Patrizia Fanasch E-Mail Patrizia.Fanasch@uni-paderborn.de Affiliation Department of Management,

More information

Gasoline Empirical Analysis: Competition Bureau March 2005

Gasoline Empirical Analysis: Competition Bureau March 2005 Gasoline Empirical Analysis: Update of Four Elements of the January 2001 Conference Board study: "The Final Fifteen Feet of Hose: The Canadian Gasoline Industry in the Year 2000" Competition Bureau March

More information

The premium for organic wines

The premium for organic wines Enometrics XV Collioure May 29-31, 2008 Estimating a hedonic price equation from the producer side Points of interest: - assessing whether there is a premium for organic wines, and which one - estimating

More information

The aim of the thesis is to determine the economic efficiency of production factors utilization in S.C. AGROINDUSTRIALA BUCIUM S.A.

The aim of the thesis is to determine the economic efficiency of production factors utilization in S.C. AGROINDUSTRIALA BUCIUM S.A. The aim of the thesis is to determine the economic efficiency of production factors utilization in S.C. AGROINDUSTRIALA BUCIUM S.A. The research objectives are: to study the history and importance of grape

More information

AJAE Appendix: Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship

AJAE Appendix: Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship AJAE Appendix: Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship Juliano Assunção Department of Economics PUC-Rio Luis H. B. Braido Graduate School of Economics Getulio

More information

Preview. Introduction (cont.) Introduction. Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost

Preview. Introduction (cont.) Introduction. Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade Wages

More information

Online Appendix to. Are Two heads Better Than One: Team versus Individual Play in Signaling Games. David C. Cooper and John H.

Online Appendix to. Are Two heads Better Than One: Team versus Individual Play in Signaling Games. David C. Cooper and John H. Online Appendix to Are Two heads Better Than One: Team versus Individual Play in Signaling Games David C. Cooper and John H. Kagel This appendix contains a discussion of the robustness of the regression

More information

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model. Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade Wages

More information

Recent U.S. Trade Patterns (2000-9) PP542. World Trade 1929 versus U.S. Top Trading Partners (Nov 2009) Why Do Countries Trade?

Recent U.S. Trade Patterns (2000-9) PP542. World Trade 1929 versus U.S. Top Trading Partners (Nov 2009) Why Do Countries Trade? PP542 Trade Recent U.S. Trade Patterns (2000-9) K. Dominguez, Winter 2010 1 K. Dominguez, Winter 2010 2 U.S. Top Trading Partners (Nov 2009) World Trade 1929 versus 2009 4 K. Dominguez, Winter 2010 3 K.

More information

International Trade CHAPTER 3: THE CLASSICAL WORL OF DAVID RICARDO AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

International Trade CHAPTER 3: THE CLASSICAL WORL OF DAVID RICARDO AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE International Trade CHAPTER 3: THE CLASSICAL WORL OF DAVID RICARDO AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE INTRODUCTION The Classical economist David Ricardo introduced the comparative advantage in The Principles of

More information

Can German Wine Cooperatives Compete on Quality?

Can German Wine Cooperatives Compete on Quality? Can German Wine Cooperatives Compete on Quality? Guenter Schamel Free University of Bozen-Bolzano School of Economics and Management Via Sernesi 1, I-39100 Bozen-Bolzano, Italy email: guenter.schamel@unibz.it

More information

An application of cumulative prospect theory to travel time variability

An application of cumulative prospect theory to travel time variability Katrine Hjorth (DTU) Stefan Flügel, Farideh Ramjerdi (TØI) An application of cumulative prospect theory to travel time variability Sixth workshop on discrete choice models at EPFL August 19-21, 2010 Page

More information

7 th Annual Conference AAWE, Stellenbosch, Jun 2013

7 th Annual Conference AAWE, Stellenbosch, Jun 2013 The Impact of the Legal System and Incomplete Contracts on Grape Sourcing Strategies: A Comparative Analysis of the South African and New Zealand Wine Industries * Corresponding Author Monnane, M. Monnane,

More information

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model. Pearson Education Limited All rights reserved.

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model. Pearson Education Limited All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model 1-1 Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade

More information

Wine-Tasting by Numbers: Using Binary Logistic Regression to Reveal the Preferences of Experts

Wine-Tasting by Numbers: Using Binary Logistic Regression to Reveal the Preferences of Experts Wine-Tasting by Numbers: Using Binary Logistic Regression to Reveal the Preferences of Experts When you need to understand situations that seem to defy data analysis, you may be able to use techniques

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Gender and firm-size: Evidence from Africa

Volume 30, Issue 1. Gender and firm-size: Evidence from Africa Volume 30, Issue 1 Gender and firm-size: Evidence from Africa Mohammad Amin World Bank Abstract A number of studies show that relative to male owned businesses, female owned businesses are smaller in size.

More information

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade Wages

More information

Preview. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade Wages

More information

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model 1-1 Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities Gains from trade

More information

1/17/manufacturing-jobs-used-to-pay-really-well-notanymore-e/

1/17/manufacturing-jobs-used-to-pay-really-well-notanymore-e/ http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/0 1/17/manufacturing-jobs-used-to-pay-really-well-notanymore-e/ Krugman s Trade Policy History Course: https://webspace.princeton.edu/users/pkrugman/wws%205

More information

To make wine, to sell the grapes or to deliver them to a cooperative: determinants of the allocation of the grapes

To make wine, to sell the grapes or to deliver them to a cooperative: determinants of the allocation of the grapes American Association of Wine Economists (AAWE) 10 th Annual Conference Bordeaux June 21-25, 2016 To make wine, to sell the grapes or to deliver them to a cooperative: determinants of the allocation of

More information

Appendix A. Table A.1: Logit Estimates for Elasticities

Appendix A. Table A.1: Logit Estimates for Elasticities Estimates from historical sales data Appendix A Table A.1. reports the estimates from the discrete choice model for the historical sales data. Table A.1: Logit Estimates for Elasticities Dependent Variable:

More information

Chapter 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Chapter 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Krugman, P.R., Obstfeld, M.: International Economics: Theory and Policy, 8th Edition, Pearson Addison-Wesley, 27-53 1 Preview

More information

Relationships Among Wine Prices, Ratings, Advertising, and Production: Examining a Giffen Good

Relationships Among Wine Prices, Ratings, Advertising, and Production: Examining a Giffen Good Relationships Among Wine Prices, Ratings, Advertising, and Production: Examining a Giffen Good Carol Miu Massachusetts Institute of Technology Abstract It has become increasingly popular for statistics

More information

BORDEAUX WINE VINTAGE QUALITY AND THE WEATHER ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS

BORDEAUX WINE VINTAGE QUALITY AND THE WEATHER ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS BORDEAUX WINE VINTAGE QUALITY AND THE WEATHER ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS WINE PRICES OVER VINTAGES DATA The data sheet contains market prices for a collection of 13 high quality Bordeaux wines (not including

More information

Italian Wine Market Structure & Consumer Demand. A. Stasi, A. Seccia, G. Nardone

Italian Wine Market Structure & Consumer Demand. A. Stasi, A. Seccia, G. Nardone Italian Wine Market Structure & Consumer Demand A. Stasi, A. Seccia, G. Nardone Outline Introduction: wine market and wineries diversity Aim of the work Theoretical discussion: market shares vs. demand

More information

Emerging Local Food Systems in the Caribbean and Southern USA July 6, 2014

Emerging Local Food Systems in the Caribbean and Southern USA July 6, 2014 Consumers attitudes toward consumption of two different types of juice beverages based on country of origin (local vs. imported) Presented at Emerging Local Food Systems in the Caribbean and Southern USA

More information

International Wine Trade: Analyzing the Value of Reputation and Quality Signals

International Wine Trade: Analyzing the Value of Reputation and Quality Signals International Wine Trade: Analyzing the Value of Reputation and Quality Signals Günter Schamel Dept of Ag Economics and Social Sciences Humboldt University at Berlin Berlin, Germany 10099 g.schamel@rz.hu-berlin.de

More information

Work Sample (Minimum) for 10-K Integration Assignment MAN and for suppliers of raw materials and services that the Company relies on.

Work Sample (Minimum) for 10-K Integration Assignment MAN and for suppliers of raw materials and services that the Company relies on. Work Sample (Minimum) for 10-K Integration Assignment MAN 4720 Employee Name: Your name goes here Company: Starbucks Date of Your Report: Date of 10-K: PESTEL 1. Political: Pg. 5 The Company supports the

More information

OF THE VARIOUS DECIDUOUS and

OF THE VARIOUS DECIDUOUS and (9) PLAXICO, JAMES S. 1955. PROBLEMS OF FACTOR-PRODUCT AGGRE- GATION IN COBB-DOUGLAS VALUE PRODUCTIVITY ANALYSIS. JOUR. FARM ECON. 37: 644-675, ILLUS. (10) SCHICKELE, RAINER. 1941. EFFECT OF TENURE SYSTEMS

More information

FACTORS DETERMINING UNITED STATES IMPORTS OF COFFEE

FACTORS DETERMINING UNITED STATES IMPORTS OF COFFEE 12 November 1953 FACTORS DETERMINING UNITED STATES IMPORTS OF COFFEE The present paper is the first in a series which will offer analyses of the factors that account for the imports into the United States

More information

ANALYSIS OF THE EVOLUTION AND DISTRIBUTION OF MAIZE CULTIVATED AREA AND PRODUCTION IN ROMANIA

ANALYSIS OF THE EVOLUTION AND DISTRIBUTION OF MAIZE CULTIVATED AREA AND PRODUCTION IN ROMANIA ANALYSIS OF THE EVOLUTION AND DISTRIBUTION OF MAIZE CULTIVATED AREA AND PRODUCTION IN ROMANIA Agatha POPESCU University of Agricultural Sciences and Veterinary Medicine, Bucharest, 59 Marasti, District

More information

Dietary Diversity in Urban and Rural China: An Endogenous Variety Approach

Dietary Diversity in Urban and Rural China: An Endogenous Variety Approach Dietary Diversity in Urban and Rural China: An Endogenous Variety Approach Jing Liu September 6, 2011 Road Map What is endogenous variety? Why is it? A structural framework illustrating this idea An application

More information

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor

More information

Flexible Working Arrangements, Collaboration, ICT and Innovation

Flexible Working Arrangements, Collaboration, ICT and Innovation Flexible Working Arrangements, Collaboration, ICT and Innovation A Panel Data Analysis Cristian Rotaru and Franklin Soriano Analytical Services Unit Economic Measurement Group (EMG) Workshop, Sydney 28-29

More information

Gender and Firm-size: Evidence from Africa

Gender and Firm-size: Evidence from Africa World Bank From the SelectedWorks of Mohammad Amin March, 2010 Gender and Firm-size: Evidence from Africa Mohammad Amin Available at: https://works.bepress.com/mohammad_amin/20/ Gender and Firm size: Evidence

More information

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries. Patrizia Fanasch University of Paderborn, Germany

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries. Patrizia Fanasch University of Paderborn, Germany Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries University of Paderborn, Germany Motivation Demand (Customer) Rising awareness and interest in organic products

More information

Demand, Supply and Market Equilibrium. Lecture 4 Shahid Iqbal

Demand, Supply and Market Equilibrium. Lecture 4 Shahid Iqbal Demand, Supply and Market Equilibrium Lecture 4 Shahid Iqbal Markets & Economics A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. The terms supply and demand refer to the behavior

More information

Return to wine: A comparison of the hedonic, repeat sales, and hybrid approaches

Return to wine: A comparison of the hedonic, repeat sales, and hybrid approaches Return to wine: A comparison of the hedonic, repeat sales, and hybrid approaches James J. Fogarty a* and Callum Jones b a School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, The University of Western Australia,

More information

Chapter 1: The Ricardo Model

Chapter 1: The Ricardo Model Chapter 1: The Ricardo Model The main question of the Ricardo model is why should countries trade? There are some countries that are better in producing a lot of goods compared to other countries. Imagine

More information

This appendix tabulates results summarized in Section IV of our paper, and also reports the results of additional tests.

This appendix tabulates results summarized in Section IV of our paper, and also reports the results of additional tests. Internet Appendix for Mutual Fund Trading Pressure: Firm-level Stock Price Impact and Timing of SEOs, by Mozaffar Khan, Leonid Kogan and George Serafeim. * This appendix tabulates results summarized in

More information

Grape Growers of Ontario Developing key measures to critically look at the grape and wine industry

Grape Growers of Ontario Developing key measures to critically look at the grape and wine industry Grape Growers of Ontario Developing key measures to critically look at the grape and wine industry March 2012 Background and scope of the project Background The Grape Growers of Ontario GGO is looking

More information

Religion and Innovation

Religion and Innovation Religion and Innovation Roland Bénabou Davide Ticchi Andrea Vindigni Princeton University IMT Lucca IMT Lucca & NBER & CIFAR Collegio Carlo Alberto American Economic Review P&P (2015) Introduction Economics

More information

A Hedonic Analysis of Retail Italian Vinegars. Summary. The Model. Vinegar. Methodology. Survey. Results. Concluding remarks.

A Hedonic Analysis of Retail Italian Vinegars. Summary. The Model. Vinegar. Methodology. Survey. Results. Concluding remarks. Vineyard Data Quantification Society "Economists at the service of Wine & Vine" Enometrics XX A Hedonic Analysis of Retail Italian Vinegars Luigi Galletto, Luca Rossetto Research Center for Viticulture

More information

Fleurieu zone (other)

Fleurieu zone (other) Fleurieu zone (other) Incorporating Southern Fleurieu and Kangaroo Island wine regions, as well as the remainder of the Fleurieu zone outside all GI regions Regional summary report 2006 South Australian

More information

Buying Filberts On a Sample Basis

Buying Filberts On a Sample Basis E 55 m ^7q Buying Filberts On a Sample Basis Special Report 279 September 1969 Cooperative Extension Service c, 789/0 ite IP") 0, i mi 1910 S R e, `g,,ttsoliktill:torvti EARs srin ITQ, E,6

More information

wine 1 wine 2 wine 3 person person person person person

wine 1 wine 2 wine 3 person person person person person 1. A trendy wine bar set up an experiment to evaluate the quality of 3 different wines. Five fine connoisseurs of wine were asked to taste each of the wine and give it a rating between 0 and 10. The order

More information

Foodservice EUROPE. 10 countries analyzed: AUSTRIA BELGIUM FRANCE GERMANY ITALY NETHERLANDS PORTUGAL SPAIN SWITZERLAND UK

Foodservice EUROPE. 10 countries analyzed: AUSTRIA BELGIUM FRANCE GERMANY ITALY NETHERLANDS PORTUGAL SPAIN SWITZERLAND UK Foodservice EUROPE MARKET INSIGHTS & CHALLENGES 2015 2016 2017 2020 Innovative European Foodservice Experts 18, avenue Marcel Anthonioz BP 28 01220 Divonne-les-Bains - France 10 countries analyzed: AUSTRIA

More information

Team Harvard Ecureuils Harvard University

Team Harvard Ecureuils Harvard University Case Question Team Harvard Ecureuils Harvard University Maxence BODDAERT Jonathan XU Jules THIERY Princeton University Graduate Consulting Club Case Competition 2016 Goals of this presentation Provide

More information

The R&D-patent relationship: An industry perspective

The R&D-patent relationship: An industry perspective Université Libre de Bruxelles (ULB) Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management (SBS-EM) European Center for Advanced Research in Economics and Statistics (ECARES) The R&D-patent relationship: An

More information

Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg., Heft 5, 2015, Online- Anhang

Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg., Heft 5, 2015, Online- Anhang I Are Joiners Trusters? A Panel Analysis of Participation and Generalized Trust Online Appendix Katrin Botzen University of Bern, Institute of Sociology, Fabrikstrasse 8, 3012 Bern, Switzerland; katrin.botzen@soz.unibe.ch

More information

2016 China Dry Bean Historical production And Estimated planting intentions Analysis

2016 China Dry Bean Historical production And Estimated planting intentions Analysis 2016 China Dry Bean Historical production And Estimated planting intentions Analysis Performed by Fairman International Business Consulting 1 of 10 P a g e I. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY A. Overall Bean Planting

More information

Wine Futures: Pricing and Allocation as Levers against Quality Uncertainty

Wine Futures: Pricing and Allocation as Levers against Quality Uncertainty Padua 2017 Abstract Submission I want to submit an abstract for: Conference Presentation Corresponding Author Burak Kazaz E-Mail bkazaz@syr.edu Affiliation Syracuse University, Whitman School of Management

More information

HONDURAS. A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming A QUICK SCAN ON IMPROVING THE ECONOMIC VIABILITY OF COFFEE FARMING

HONDURAS. A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming A QUICK SCAN ON IMPROVING THE ECONOMIC VIABILITY OF COFFEE FARMING HONDURAS A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming 1 OBJECTIVES OF STUDY Overall objective Identify opportunities for potential benefits to coffee farmers from improved farm profitability

More information

QUALITY, PRICING AND THE PERFORMANCE OF THE WHEAT INDUSTRY IN SOUTH AFRICA

QUALITY, PRICING AND THE PERFORMANCE OF THE WHEAT INDUSTRY IN SOUTH AFRICA QUALITY, PRICING AND THE PERFORMANCE OF THE WHEAT INDUSTRY IN SOUTH AFRICA 21 September 2015 Dr Johnny van der Merwe Lecturer / Agricultural economics (Prof HD van Schalkwyk and Dr PC Cloete) So what motivated

More information

Labor Supply of Married Couples in the Formal and Informal Sectors in Thailand

Labor Supply of Married Couples in the Formal and Informal Sectors in Thailand Southeast Asian Journal of Economics 2(2), December 2014: 77-102 Labor Supply of Married Couples in the Formal and Informal Sectors in Thailand Chairat Aemkulwat 1 Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University

More information

International Journal of Business and Commerce Vol. 3, No.8: Apr 2014[01-10] (ISSN: )

International Journal of Business and Commerce Vol. 3, No.8: Apr 2014[01-10] (ISSN: ) The Comparative Influences of Relationship Marketing, National Cultural values, and Consumer values on Consumer Satisfaction between Local and Global Coffee Shop Brands Yi Hsu Corresponding author: Associate

More information

Memorandum of understanding

Memorandum of understanding European Organic Wine Carta (EOWC) Memorandum of understanding 1. Preamble The common European Organic Wine Carta (EOWC) is a private, market-oriented and open initiative to promote and encourage organic

More information

A Note on a Test for the Sum of Ranksums*

A Note on a Test for the Sum of Ranksums* Journal of Wine Economics, Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2007, Pages 98 102 A Note on a Test for the Sum of Ranksums* Richard E. Quandt a I. Introduction In wine tastings, in which several tasters (judges)

More information

Relation between Grape Wine Quality and Related Physicochemical Indexes

Relation between Grape Wine Quality and Related Physicochemical Indexes Research Journal of Applied Sciences, Engineering and Technology 5(4): 557-5577, 013 ISSN: 040-7459; e-issn: 040-7467 Maxwell Scientific Organization, 013 Submitted: October 1, 01 Accepted: December 03,

More information

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

Reading Essentials and Study Guide Lesson 1 Absolute and Comparative Advantage ESSENTIAL QUESTION How does trade benefit all participating parties? Reading HELPDESK Academic Vocabulary volume amount; quantity enables made possible Content

More information

The Financing and Growth of Firms in China and India: Evidence from Capital Markets

The Financing and Growth of Firms in China and India: Evidence from Capital Markets The Financing and Growth of Firms in China and India: Evidence from Capital Markets Tatiana Didier Sergio Schmukler Dec. 12-13, 2012 NIPFP-DEA-JIMF Conference Macro and Financial Challenges of Emerging

More information

MBA 503 Final Project Guidelines and Rubric

MBA 503 Final Project Guidelines and Rubric MBA 503 Final Project Guidelines and Rubric Overview There are two summative assessments for this course. For your first assessment, you will be objectively assessed by your completion of a series of MyAccountingLab

More information

Structures of Life. Investigation 1: Origin of Seeds. Big Question: 3 rd Science Notebook. Name:

Structures of Life. Investigation 1: Origin of Seeds. Big Question: 3 rd Science Notebook. Name: 3 rd Science Notebook Structures of Life Investigation 1: Origin of Seeds Name: Big Question: What are the properties of seeds and how does water affect them? 1 Alignment with New York State Science Standards

More information

COUNTRY PLAN 2017: TANZANIA

COUNTRY PLAN 2017: TANZANIA COUNTRY PLAN 2017: TANZANIA COUNTRY PLAN 2017: TANZANIA VISION2020 PRIORITIES AND NATIONAL STRATEGY PRIORITIES Vision2020 SDG s No poverty Quality education Gender equality Decent work Responsible Production

More information

Valuation in the Life Settlements Market

Valuation in the Life Settlements Market Valuation in the Life Settlements Market New Empirical Evidence Jiahua (Java) Xu 1 1 Institute of Insurance Economics University of St.Gallen Western Risk and Insurance Association 2018 Annual Meeting

More information

Red wine consumption in the new world and the old world

Red wine consumption in the new world and the old world Red wine consumption in the new world and the old world World red wine market is expanding. In 2012, the total red wine trade was over 32 billion dollar,most current research on wine focus on the Old World:

More information

Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model Introduction Theories of why trade occurs: Differences across countries in labor, labor skills, physical capital, natural resources,

More information

DERIVED DEMAND FOR FRESH CHEESE PRODUCTS IMPORTED INTO JAPAN

DERIVED DEMAND FOR FRESH CHEESE PRODUCTS IMPORTED INTO JAPAN PBTC 05-04 PBTC 02-6 DERIVED DEMAND FOR FRESH CHEESE PRODUCTS IMPORTED INTO JAPAN By Andreas P. Christou, Richard L. Kilmer, James A. Stearns, Shiferaw T. Feleke, & Jiaoju Ge PBTC 05-04 September 2005

More information

Evaluating Population Forecast Accuracy: A Regression Approach Using County Data

Evaluating Population Forecast Accuracy: A Regression Approach Using County Data Evaluating Population Forecast Accuracy: A Regression Approach Using County Data Jeff Tayman, UC San Diego Stanley K. Smith, University of Florida Stefan Rayer, University of Florida Final formatted version

More information

Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool? Online Appendix September 2014

Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool? Online Appendix September 2014 Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool? 1. Data Construction Online Appendix September 2014 The data consist of the Association s records on all coffee acquisitions

More information

Joseph G. Alfieri 1, William P. Kustas 1, John H. Prueger 2, Lynn G. McKee 1, Feng Gao 1 Lawrence E. Hipps 3, Sebastian Los 3

Joseph G. Alfieri 1, William P. Kustas 1, John H. Prueger 2, Lynn G. McKee 1, Feng Gao 1 Lawrence E. Hipps 3, Sebastian Los 3 Joseph G. Alfieri 1, William P. Kustas 1, John H. Prueger 2, Lynn G. McKee 1, Feng Gao 1 Lawrence E. Hipps 3, Sebastian Los 3 1 USDA, ARS, Hydrology & Remote Sensing Lab, Beltsville MD 2 USDA,ARS, National

More information

Trade Integration and Method of Payments in International Transactions

Trade Integration and Method of Payments in International Transactions Trade Integration and Method of Payments in International Transactions Veysel Avşar College of Business - TAMUCC & Alexis Habiyaremye Human Sciences Research Council Cape Town, South Africa Introduction

More information

The 2006 Economic Impact of Nebraska Wineries and Grape Growers

The 2006 Economic Impact of Nebraska Wineries and Grape Growers A Bureau of Business Economic Impact Analysis From the University of Nebraska Lincoln The 2006 Economic Impact of Nebraska Wineries and Grape Growers Dr. Eric Thompson Seth Freudenburg Prepared for The

More information

J / A V 9 / N O.

J / A V 9 / N O. July/Aug 2003 Volume 9 / NO. 7 See Story on Page 4 Implications for California Walnut Producers By Mechel S. Paggi, Ph.D. Global production of walnuts is forecast to be up 3 percent in 2002/03 reaching

More information

Gail E. Potter, Timo Smieszek, and Kerstin Sailer. April 24, 2015

Gail E. Potter, Timo Smieszek, and Kerstin Sailer. April 24, 2015 Supplementary Material to Modelling workplace contact networks: the effects of organizational structure, architecture, and reporting errors on epidemic predictions, published in Network Science Gail E.

More information

The state of the European GI wines sector: a comparative analysis of performance

The state of the European GI wines sector: a comparative analysis of performance The state of the European GI wines sector: a comparative analysis of performance Special Report November 2017 1. Overview of a growing global wine market Wine is one of the most globalised products. The

More information

Lesson 23: Newton s Law of Cooling

Lesson 23: Newton s Law of Cooling Student Outcomes Students apply knowledge of exponential functions and transformations of functions to a contextual situation. Lesson Notes Newton s Law of Cooling is a complex topic that appears in physics

More information

ETHIOPIA. A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming A QUICK SCAN ON IMPROVING THE ECONOMIC VIABILITY OF COFFEE FARMING

ETHIOPIA. A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming A QUICK SCAN ON IMPROVING THE ECONOMIC VIABILITY OF COFFEE FARMING ETHIOPIA A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming 1 OBJECTIVES OF STUDY Overall objective Identify opportunities for potential benefits to coffee farmers from improved farm profitability

More information

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF WINE AND WINE GRAPES ON THE STATE OF TEXAS 2015

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF WINE AND WINE GRAPES ON THE STATE OF TEXAS 2015 THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF WINE AND WINE GRAPES ON THE STATE OF TEXAS 2015 A Frank, Rimerman + Co. LLP Report Updated January 2017 This study was commissioned by the Texas Wine and Grape Growers Association

More information

Tourism and HSR in Spain. Does the AVE increase local visitors?

Tourism and HSR in Spain. Does the AVE increase local visitors? 2 nd Meeting on Transport Economics and Infrastructure Barcelona January 21 st 2016 Tourism and HSR in Spain. Does the AVE increase local visitors? Javier Campos (ULPGC) Daniel Albalate (UB) Juan Luis

More information

Financing Decisions of REITs and the Switching Effect

Financing Decisions of REITs and the Switching Effect Financing Decisions of REITs and the Switching Effect By Lucia Gibilaro University of Bergamo Department of Management, Economics and Quantitative Methods and Gianluca Mattarocci University of Rome Tor

More information

Uniform Rules Update Final EIR APPENDIX 6 ASSUMPTIONS AND CALCULATIONS USED FOR ESTIMATING TRAFFIC VOLUMES

Uniform Rules Update Final EIR APPENDIX 6 ASSUMPTIONS AND CALCULATIONS USED FOR ESTIMATING TRAFFIC VOLUMES APPENDIX 6 ASSUMPTIONS AND CALCULATIONS USED FOR ESTIMATING TRAFFIC VOLUMES ASSUMPTIONS AND CALCULATIONS USED FOR ESTIMATING TRAFFIC VOLUMES This appendix contains the assumptions that have been applied

More information

Nuclear reactors construction costs: The role of lead-time, standardization and technological progress

Nuclear reactors construction costs: The role of lead-time, standardization and technological progress Nuclear reactors construction costs: The role of lead-time, standardization and technological progress Lina Escobar Rangel and Michel Berthélemy Mines ParisTech - Centre for Industrial Economics CERNA

More information

Internet Appendix. For. Birds of a feather: Value implications of political alignment between top management and directors

Internet Appendix. For. Birds of a feather: Value implications of political alignment between top management and directors Internet Appendix For Birds of a feather: Value implications of political alignment between top management and directors Jongsub Lee *, Kwang J. Lee, and Nandu J. Nagarajan This Internet Appendix reports

More information

Decision making with incomplete information Some new developments. Rudolf Vetschera University of Vienna. Tamkang University May 15, 2017

Decision making with incomplete information Some new developments. Rudolf Vetschera University of Vienna. Tamkang University May 15, 2017 Decision making with incomplete information Some new developments Rudolf Vetschera University of Vienna Tamkang University May 15, 2017 Agenda Problem description Overview of methods Single parameter approaches

More information

STATE OF THE VITIVINICULTURE WORLD MARKET

STATE OF THE VITIVINICULTURE WORLD MARKET STATE OF THE VITIVINICULTURE WORLD MARKET April 2015 1 Table of contents 1. 2014 VITIVINICULTURAL PRODUCTION POTENTIAL 3 2. WINE PRODUCTION 5 3. WINE CONSUMPTION 7 4. INTERNATIONAL TRADE 9 Abbreviations:

More information

CERT Exceptions ED 19 en. Exceptions. Explanatory Document. Valid from: 26/09/2018 Distribution: Public

CERT Exceptions ED 19 en. Exceptions. Explanatory Document. Valid from: 26/09/2018 Distribution: Public 19 en Exceptions Explanatory Document Valid from: 26/09/2018 Distribution: Public Table of contents 1 Purpose... 3 2 Area of Application... 3 3 Process... 3 4 Category A exceptions: generally accepted

More information

Effects of political-economic integration and trade liberalization on exports of Italian Quality Wines Produced in Determined Regions (QWPDR)

Effects of political-economic integration and trade liberalization on exports of Italian Quality Wines Produced in Determined Regions (QWPDR) Effects of political-economic integration and trade liberalization on exports of Italian Quality Wines Produced in Determined Regions (QWPDR) G. De Blasi, A. Seccia, D. Carlucci, F. G. Santeramo Department

More information

How Should Vegans Live?

How Should Vegans Live? How Should Vegans Live 61 How Should Vegans Live? Xavier Cohen University of Oxford Abstract In this essay, I look at the significant portion of vegans who are vegan because they care about harm to animals.

More information

Internet Appendix for Does Stock Liquidity Enhance or Impede Firm Innovation? *

Internet Appendix for Does Stock Liquidity Enhance or Impede Firm Innovation? * Internet Appendix for Does Stock Liquidity Enhance or Impede Firm Innovation? * This Internet Appendix provides supplemental analyses and robustness tests to the main results presented in Does Stock Liquidity

More information

The Roles of Social Media and Expert Reviews in the Market for High-End Goods: An Example Using Bordeaux and California Wines

The Roles of Social Media and Expert Reviews in the Market for High-End Goods: An Example Using Bordeaux and California Wines The Roles of Social Media and Expert Reviews in the Market for High-End Goods: An Example Using Bordeaux and California Wines Alex Albright, Stanford/Harvard University Peter Pedroni, Williams College

More information

Determining the Optimum Time to Pick Gwen

Determining the Optimum Time to Pick Gwen California Avocado Society 1988 Yearbook 72: 209-214 Determining the Optimum Time to Pick Gwen Gray Martin and Bob Bergh Department of Botany and Plant Sciences, University of California, Riverside. Predicting

More information

Origin-based products: From local culture to legal protection

Origin-based products: From local culture to legal protection Origin-based products: From local culture to legal protection Laurence Bérard American Origin Products and the TTIP: Collaboration for Rural Development First Research Leaders Meeting University of Arkansas,

More information

Investment Wines. - Risk Analysis. Prepared by: Michael Shortell & Adiam Woldetensae Date: 06/09/2015

Investment Wines. - Risk Analysis. Prepared by: Michael Shortell & Adiam Woldetensae Date: 06/09/2015 Investment Wines - Risk Analysis Prepared by: Michael Shortell & Adiam Woldetensae Date: 06/09/2015 Purpose Look at investment wines & examine factors that affect wine prices over time We will identify

More information

IMSI Annual Business Meeting Amherst, Massachusetts October 26, 2008

IMSI Annual Business Meeting Amherst, Massachusetts October 26, 2008 Consumer Research to Support a Standardized Grading System for Pure Maple Syrup Presented to: IMSI Annual Business Meeting Amherst, Massachusetts October 26, 2008 Objectives The objectives for the study

More information

RESEARCH UPDATE from Texas Wine Marketing Research Institute by Natalia Kolyesnikova, PhD Tim Dodd, PhD THANK YOU SPONSORS

RESEARCH UPDATE from Texas Wine Marketing Research Institute by Natalia Kolyesnikova, PhD Tim Dodd, PhD THANK YOU SPONSORS RESEARCH UPDATE from by Natalia Kolyesnikova, PhD Tim Dodd, PhD THANK YOU SPONSORS STUDY 1 Identifying the Characteristics & Behavior of Consumer Segments in Texas Introduction Some wine industries depend

More information