Employers higher education and fixed term contracts: Individual vs spillover effects

Similar documents
Volume 30, Issue 1. Gender and firm-size: Evidence from Africa

Gender and Firm-size: Evidence from Africa

ICT Use and Exports. Patricia Kotnik, Eva Hagsten. This is a working draft. Please do not cite or quote without permission of the authors.

Looking Long: Demographic Change, Economic Crisis, and the Prospects for Reducing Poverty. La Conyuntura vs. the Long-run

"Primary agricultural commodity trade and labour market outcome

*p <.05. **p <.01. ***p <.001.

Flexible Working Arrangements, Collaboration, ICT and Innovation

To make wine, to sell the grapes or to deliver them to a cooperative: determinants of the allocation of the grapes

CHAPTER I BACKGROUND

Perspective of the Labor Market for security guards in Israel in time of terror attacks

Gasoline Empirical Analysis: Competition Bureau March 2005

Labor Supply of Married Couples in the Formal and Informal Sectors in Thailand

Nuclear reactors construction costs: The role of lead-time, standardization and technological progress

Sickness Absences of Self-employed Male Workers: Fewer but Longer

Relationships Among Wine Prices, Ratings, Advertising, and Production: Examining a Giffen Good

Religion and Innovation

A Web Survey Analysis of the Subjective Well-being of Spanish Workers

POSITION DESCRIPTION. DATE OF VERSION: January Position Summary:

Long term impacts of facilitating temporary contracts: A comparative analysis of Italy and Spain using birth cohorts

Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of Eco-certification on the Performance of German Wineries Patrizia FANASCH

The premium for organic wines

Power and Priorities: Gender, Caste, and Household Bargaining in India

Coffee Price Volatility and Intra-household Labour Supply: Evidence from Vietnam

Work Sample (Minimum) for 10-K Integration Assignment MAN and for suppliers of raw materials and services that the Company relies on.

Credit Supply and Monetary Policy: Identifying the Bank Balance-Sheet Channel with Loan Applications. Web Appendix

Online Appendix. for. Female Leadership and Gender Equity: Evidence from Plant Closure

Appendix A. Table A1: Marginal effects and elasticities on the export probability

Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg., Heft 5, 2015, Online- Anhang

7 th Annual Conference AAWE, Stellenbosch, Jun 2013

Appendix A. Table A.1: Logit Estimates for Elasticities

AJAE Appendix: Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship

ARE THERE SKILLS PAYOFFS IN LOW AND MIDDLE-INCOME COUNTRIES?

ONLINE APPENDIX APPENDIX A. DESCRIPTION OF U.S. NON-FARM PRIVATE SECTORS AND INDUSTRIES

THE SCALEUP MANIFESTO: HOW BRITAIN IS BECOMING THE SCALEUP NATION OF THE WORLD. London School of Economics, November 2016

POSITION DESCRIPTION. DATE OF VERSION: August Position Summary:

Tourism and HSR in Spain. Does the AVE increase local visitors?

The determinantsof charitable givingin Belgium

Trade Integration and Method of Payments in International Transactions

Effects of political-economic integration and trade liberalization on exports of Italian Quality Wines Produced in Determined Regions (QWPDR)

What are the Driving Forces for Arts and Culture Related Activities in Japan?

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Introduction (cont.) Introduction. Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost

Food and beverage services statistics - NACE Rev. 2

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Wine-Tasting by Numbers: Using Binary Logistic Regression to Reveal the Preferences of Experts

Modeling Regional Endogenous Growth

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model. Pearson Education Limited All rights reserved.

Recent U.S. Trade Patterns (2000-9) PP542. World Trade 1929 versus U.S. Top Trading Partners (Nov 2009) Why Do Countries Trade?


Multiple Imputation for Missing Data in KLoSA

Aging, Social Capital, and Health Care Utilization in the Province of Ontario, Canada

Method for the imputation of the earnings variable in the Belgian LFS

The Roles of Social Media and Expert Reviews in the Market for High-End Goods: An Example Using Bordeaux and California Wines

Comparative Analysis of Fresh and Dried Fish Consumption in Ondo State, Nigeria

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Characteristics of U.S. Veal Consumers

Technical Memorandum: Economic Impact of the Tutankhamun and the Golden Age of the Pharoahs Exhibition

Promotion Strategy and Financial Policy -The Wine Industry in Hokkaido Japan -

The Diffusion of Informal Knowledge and Innovation Performance: A sectoral approach. M. Abraham Garcia-Torres and Hugo Hollanders

Senior poverty in Canada, : A decomposition analysis of income and poverty rates

Chapter 1: The Ricardo Model

FRANCHISING. PRESENTED BY: Beant Singh Roll No MBA I (F)

Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional effects: Balancing diversity and focus. Anne Moroney.

What does radical price change and choice reveal?

MBA 503 Final Project Guidelines and Rubric

Effects of Election Results on Stock Price Performance: Evidence from 1976 to 2008

Smart Specialisation Strategy for REMTh: setting priorities

Economic Contributions of the Florida Citrus Industry in and for Reduced Production

The Inclusiveness of Africa s Recent High- Growth Episode: Evidence from Six Countries

Chukyo University Institute of Economics Discussion Paper Series

Predicting Wine Quality

Sustainable Coffee Challenge FAQ

PRIVATE AND PUBLIC MERGER WAVES

IT and Firm Performance:

Selection bias in innovation studies: A simple test

CENTRAL OTAGO WINEGROWERS ASSOCIATION (INC.)

Eestimated coefficient. t-value

Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

FAIR TRADE WESTERN PURPLE PAPER

Should We Put Ice in Wine? A Difference-in-Differences Approach from Switzerland

REMARKS BY PAUL BULCKE, GROUP CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER, NESTLÉ S.A. MEDIA CONFERENCE, NAIROBI, FRIDAY, JULY 2, 2010

Emerging Local Food Systems in the Caribbean and Southern USA July 6, 2014

Urban Density, Human Capital, and Productivity: An empirical analysis using wage data

Running head: CASE STUDY 1

Public good contributions among coffee farmers in Costa Rica: co-operativists and private dealers

Chapter 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

DETERMINANTS OF DINER RESPONSE TO ORIENTAL CUISINE IN SPECIALITY RESTAURANTS AND SELECTED CLASSIFIED HOTELS IN NAIROBI COUNTY, KENYA

A Hedonic Analysis of Retail Italian Vinegars. Summary. The Model. Vinegar. Methodology. Survey. Results. Concluding remarks.

International Journal of Business and Commerce Vol. 3, No.8: Apr 2014[01-10] (ISSN: )

Dietary Diversity in Urban and Rural China: An Endogenous Variety Approach

The R&D-patent relationship: An industry perspective

The dawn of reproductive change in north east Italy. A microanalysis

SMALLHOLDER TEA FARMING AND VALUE CHAIN DEVELOPMENT IN CHINA

The Sources of Risk Spillovers among REITs: Asset Similarities and Regional Proximity

Occupational Structure and Social Stratification in East Asia: A Comparative Study of Japan, Korea and Taiwan

The Financing and Growth of Firms in China and India: Evidence from Capital Markets

Harvesting Charges for Florida Citrus, 2016/17

WACS culinary certification scheme

2017 FINANCIAL REVIEW

Transcription:

Employers higher education and fixed term contracts: Individual vs spillover effects Andrea Ricci Roma, 1 Luglio 2013 Workshop «Capitale Umano ed Istruzione», Università di Roma «La Sapienza»

Aims, Hypothesis and Background discussion This paper tries to integrate some hints and suggestions stemming from the literature on entrepreneurship, management practices and education on the current debate on the determinants of firms use of flexible staff arrangements We see at least 3 channels through which an high level of employers education may influence significantly firms incentives to use fixed term contracts First: Higher education favours a direct and indirect knowledge of these modern management practices that point out the competitive advantages deriving from on-thejob training, workers active involvement in productive process and flat hierarchies inside the firms (Bloon and Van Reenen, 2009; Raghuram and Wulf, 2006) Second: Attending schooling is associated to a range of cognitive skills and capabilities that enhances time patience and long-terminism in economic decisions by individuals (Oreopolous and Salvanes, 2011; Perez-Arce, 2012). Third: Attending schooling is correlated with a balance set of cognitive and no-cognitive skills that favour individual attitudes toward cooperation, fairness and proto-social behaviour. These behavioural traits, in turn, are recognized as important mechanism devices to enhance workers efforts, trust and long term employment relationships, even in presence of incomplete labour contracts (Bandiera, Barankay and Rasul,2005; Fehr, Goette and Zehnder,2008).

A Role for Employers educational spillovers Based on this bulk of suggestions, we also can consider how the agglomeration of highly educated employers may exert an external effect on the choices of the firms located in the same economic environment concerning the use of temporary contracts. In line with the literature pointing out the relevance of knowledge spillovers arising in local areas from agglomeration of educated people (Duranton and Puga, 2003; Rosenthal and Strange, 2004), we ask whether the entrepreneurial choices on the use of fixed term contract can be influenced by experiences and strategies of other employers in the same area. In the existing literature firms resort to temporary contracts as the outcome of an optimal choice following profit maximization in a given institutional/legislative framework. In our framework also socially-built preferences and strategic options of the employers matter, as the choice of temporary contracts may be influenced by the interactions among employers. Indeed, both knowledge and attitudes are partially shaped by social interactions. To this regard, the most natural and relevant channel of spillover is given by contacts and exchanges among employers and the learning descending from such interactions. Both formal and informal contacts and relationships may give rise to an exchange of information and opinions as well as can allow peer imitation (Audretsch and Keilbach, 2007)

As for small and medium enterprises, informal networks connecting employers in local areas can be regarded as a primary source of knowledge, a place where a common view can grow up and diffuse. A special role in the local networks connecting entrepreneurs is played by the consultants offering services and advices to small and medium enterprises Then, consultants and business associations can be regarded as a major channel of knowledge spillover in the local economies. A further insight into the mechanism channeling this educational spillover can be drawn from the idea of inefficient herding (Banerjee, 1992; Duranton and Puga, 2003). According to it, under uncertain demand conditions each agent bases his/her decisions upon decisions made previously by other agents in the same environment. Then, if this process of sequential choices is started by less than optimal decisions, also later choices made by other agents are likely to be inefficient. Indeed, previous choices convey a wrong signal distorting the subsequent ones. Such self-reinforcing mechanism may give rise to a suboptimal outcome. This can help to explain the exorbitant resort to fixed-term contracts even when their detrimental effect on productivity outweighs the short-term cost gains Finally, beside the knowledge spillover, also a pecuniary spillover might be in action in environments where a large number of highly educated employers are located, as the higher incidence of permanent jobs created by such employers may crowd-out temporary jobs. Assuming that, ceteris paribus, workers prefer a permanent job to a temporary one, in an economy where they are more likely to get a permanent job they are able to claim a higher wage if offered a temporary job as it is less costly for them to refuse it. As a consequence, fixed-term employment becomes less profitable for local employers and the share of fixedterm employment lowers

Data The empirical analysis is based on Employer and Employee Survey (RIL), conducted by ISFOL in 2010 on a representative sample of over 25000 partnership and limited firms operating in the non-agricultural private sector Sample selection: firms with at least 5 employees to guarantee a minimum level of organization of the internal labor markets. Further, the sample is restricted to these firms with no missing data on the key variables. Then the final sample over 10000 firms Other data source: Census 2001; Labor Force Survey (Istat)

Main Descriptive Statistics. On average, the total share of workers with fixed term contracts is about 14% of the total employment; the share of workers with fixed term contracts without training clause is 9.4% while those with fixed term contracts with on-the job training clause is 4.4%. On average, only 23% of firms are managed by an employer with a tertiary level education. Similarly, our sample presents a small incidence of firm with employers younger than 40 years (12%) with respect to those managed by employers aged between 40 and 59 years (61%) those with employers older than 60 years (27%) with those with employers older than 60 years (27%). The individual profile of the Italian employers is associated with the predominant presence of firms small in size (76%) and family-owned (90%), which typically require less formal education and skills to be managed than firms large in size and market-owned (Leazar, 2009)

Table 1: Descriptive statistics with sampling weights Mean Std dev Min Max Fixed term workers % total fixed term (FT) 0.14 0.22 0 1 % fixed term with training (FTT) 0.044 0.10 0 1 % fixed term without training (FTNT) 0.094 0.20 0 1 Employers characteristics tertiary education 0.23 0.42 0 1 entrep. age <40 0.12 0.32 0 1 39<entrep age <60 0.61 0.49 0 1 entrep. age >59 0.27 0.44 0 1 Workers characteristics % tertiary education college 0.08 0.17 0 1 % upper secondary education 0.44 0.30 0 1 % lower secondary education 0.47 0.34 0 1 % female 0.37 0.29 0 1 % trained 0.20 0.33 0 1 Firms characteristics family firm 0.90 0.30 0 1 gest_man 0.03 0.18 0 1 gest_man_int 0.07 0.26 0 1 gest_pr 0.90 0.30 0 1 product innov 0.39 0.49 0 1 process innov 0.31 0.46 0 1 local bargaining 0.06 0.24 0 1 foreign market 0.23 0.42 0 1 ln (ros) 11.66 1.21 3.14 19.50 unemployemtn rate 2009 at prov 0.07 0.03 0.02 0.19 N of obs 11026

Table 1a: Descriptive statistics with sampling weights Mean Std dev Min Max Size 5 <n. employees <15 0.76 0.43 0 1 14 <n. employees <50 0.19 0.39 0 1 49 < n. employees <250 0.04 0.20 0 1 n. employees> 249 0.01 0.08 0 1 macro regions North Ovest 0.31 0.46 0 1 North East 0.26 0.44 0 1 Centre 0.21 0.41 0 1 South 0.22 0.41 0 1 Sector Quarrying, Mining etc 0.00 0.05 0 1 manufacturing 0.29 0.45 0 1 gas, water and gas distribution 0.01 0.10 0 1 Construction 0.14 0.34 0 1 retail and wholesale 0.22 0.42 0 1 trasportation 0.03 0.18 0 1 hotels and restaurants 0.11 0.31 0 1 insurance, financial intermediation 0.01 0.12 0 1 real estate and rental 0.05 0.21 0 1 information, comunication and other business service 0.09 0.28 0 1 health, education and social services 0.02 0.15 0 1 sports, entertainment and other services 0.03 0.17 0 1 N of obs 11026

Econometric analysis: step 1 The proportion of fixed term contracts (%FT) is estimated as a function of variables measuring individual profile of employers and a set of firm levels controls using RIL Survey: (1) Different specification of equation (1) are estimated by using a linear (OLS and 2SLS-IV) regression model that makes it easier the interpretation of the coefficient estimates (Angrist and Pischke, 2009) OLS estimates are displayed in Table 2; 2SLS-IV estimates are shown in Table 3

Table 2: OLS estimates: total share of FT coeff std er coeff std er coeff std er Employer characteristics employer tertiary educ -0.021 *** 0.003-0.012 *** 0.004-0.019 *** 0.004 employer age =Young 0.046 *** 0.006 0.043 *** 0.006 0.043 *** 0.007 entrep age = middle 0.022 *** 0.003 0.022 *** 0.003 0.021 *** 0.003 Workforce characteristics % tertiary education 0.078 *** 0.012 % upper secondary education 0.006 0.007 % female 0.035 *** 0.008 % trained -0.019 *** 0.004 unemployemnt rate 2009 0.036 0.093 Firm charateristcs fam_firm 0.012 *** 0.004 0.015 *** 0.004 foreign market -0.008 ** 0.003-0.013 *** 0.004 product innov 0.008 ** 0.004 0.011 *** 0.004 process innov -0.001 0.004-0.004 0.004 local bargaining -0.033 *** 0.004-0.029 *** 0.004 ln (ros) -0.013 *** 0.001-0.013 *** 0.001 Macro-region Size classes sector dummies constant 0.049 *** 0.007 0.191 *** 0.018 0.190 *** 0.023 F(.) Prob > F R-squared N of obs Source: RIL-ISFOL data. Note: omitted variable, employer with lower education and with age more than 60; south, <4 n. of employees<15; Statistical significance *** at 1%, ** at 5%, * at 10% Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 51.17 0.00 0.14 14298 45.85 0.00 0.15 13663 31.650 0.000 0.146 11016

Table 3: 2SLS Instrumental variable regression; var dip: total share of FT coef std er coef std er coef std er coef std er Employer characteristics employer tertiary educ -0.109 *** 0.017-0.089 *** 0.024-0.108 *** 0.031 employer age =Young 0.056 *** 0.007 0.052 *** 0.007 0.052 *** 0.008 0.105 *** 0.015 entrep age = middle 0.028 *** 0.003 0.026 *** 0.003 0.025 *** 0.004 0.050 *** 0.009 Workforce characteristics % tertiary education 0.124 *** 0.021 0.483 *** 0.028 % upper secondary education 0.015 * 0.008 0.113 *** 0.014 % female 0.038 *** 0.008 0.037 ** 0.017 % trained -0.019 *** 0.004 0.005 0.011 unemployemnt rate 2009 0.105 0.098 0.803 *** 0.211 Firm charateristcs family firm -0.002 0.006 0.002 0.006-0.103 *** 0.013 foreign market -0.003 0.004-0.008 ** 0.004 0.048 *** 0.010 product innov 0.010 ** 0.004 0.011 *** 0.004-0.001 0.010 process innov -0.001 0.004-0.002 0.004 0.020 ** 0.010 local bargaining -0.023 *** 0.005-0.018 *** 0.006 0.109 *** 0.014 ln (ros) -0.011 *** 0.001-0.012 *** 0.002 0.022 *** 0.004 Macro-region Size classes sector dummies managment external 0.134 *** 0.019 recruitment share of population with 3.129 *** 0.358 tertary education in 2001 constant 0.061 *** 0.008 0.177 *** 0.022 0.179 *** 0.024-0.292 *** 0.060 Centered R2 Uncentered R2 Number of obs Source: RIL-ISFOL data. Note: omitted variable, employer with lower education and with age more than 60; south, <4 n. of employees<15; Statistical significance *** at 1%, ** at 5%, * at 10% Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 First Step 0.102 0.353 14105 0.125 0.370 13493 0.108 0.352 10926 0.27 0.51 10926

Econometric analysis: step 2 The proportion of fixed term contracts (%FT) is estimated as a function of variables measuring individual profile of employers, the agglomeration of entrepreneurial human capital and a set of firm levels controls: (2) %FT i =α educ_ grad i +β D c +δ W i +χ F i +ε i educ_grad is a dummy variable indicating whether the employer is graduated, while D c is a density indicator, specifically it is the number of employers with a tertiary level of education in the province p and sector c in which firm i is located (this is an indicator of entrepreneurial human capital spillovers). We estimate equation (2) with linear regression models: OLS and 2SLS_IV estimates are displayed in Table 4

IV estimation results: caveats Our data can be affected by a selection bias due to the fact that the sampling was carried out in a year of deep economic crisis (2010). In principle, during a crisis period the incidence of temporary jobs on total employment can either increase or decrease in the whole economy, and this trend could potentially affect all the firms included in the sample. This type of bias should amplify the effect of the covariates towards a greater/lower use of temporary jobs with respect to a pre-crisis period. In particular the empirical evidence shows that the share of temporary jobs has increased during the crisis and, in particular, over the 4 quarters of 2010. Then, the estimated coefficient our main variable (D c ), is expected to be upward biased, due to cross sectional sampling. Nevertheless, as we will discuss soon, Dc has a significantly negative impact on the share of temporary employees on total firm s employment. Therefore, the true value of the coefficient, adjusted for the recession effect, should be even more negative. This way we can clearly identify the effect of local employers aggregate human capital, even if we are not able to model directly the bias.

IV estimation Results: futher The main variables of equation (2), Dc and employer_educ, are instrumented and tests for weak instrumentation perform well demonstrating that instruments are not weak. Then Table 4 shows that Dc is negative and highly significant demonstrating that an agglomeration of high educated employers affects the firms individual decision to hire on temporary basis. This result is independent from the skill of the employer: therefore it can be argued that an agglomeration of high skill employers creates a spillover effect that on average affects the totality of the employers. The fact that the employer s individual skill is not significant while agglomeration of high skill creates a spillover is a really interesting and complex result that should be analyzed more deeply At a first glance such result seems to recall an herding effect and we can argue that such effect it is made through informational cascade which occurs when people observe the actions of others and then make the same choice that the others have made, independently of their own private information signals.

Table 4: OLS and 2SLS-IV estimates OLS 2SLS-IV coef st er coef st er Employer characteristics Dc -0.072 *** 0.024-0.381 *** 0.108 employer tertiary educ -0.012 ** 0.006 0.007 0.009 employer age =Young 0.038 *** 0.010 0.037 *** 0.010 entrep age = middle 0.019 *** 0.005 0.017 *** 0.005 Workforce characteristics % tertiary education 0.066 *** 0.019 0.053 *** 0.020 % upper secondary education -0.005 0.012-0.005 0.012 % female 0.042 *** 0.012 0.043 *** 0.012 % trained -0.026 *** 0.006-0.024 *** 0.007 % hired in 2009 0.001 *** 0.000 0.001 *** 0.000 Firm characteristics family firm 0.012 ** 0.006 0.009 0.006 firm age 0.000 *** 0.000 0.000 *** 0.000 foreign market -0.011 * 0.006-0.008 0.006 ln (ros) -0.019 *** 0.002-0.018 *** 0.002 product innov 0.013 ** 0.005 0.012 ** 0.005 process innov -0.012 ** 0.006-0.012 ** 0.006 local bargaining -0.032 *** 0.006-0.030 *** 0.006 unempl rate 2009 0.133 0.155 0.320 * 0.166 industrial district -0.030 *** 0.006-0.041 *** 0.008 Macro-region Size classes sector dummies managment external recruitment share of population with tertary education in 2001 (prov)