The impact of the National Minimum Wage on UK Businesses 1

Similar documents
Food and beverage services statistics - NACE Rev. 2

Labor Supply of Married Couples in the Formal and Informal Sectors in Thailand

ICT Use and Exports. Patricia Kotnik, Eva Hagsten. This is a working draft. Please do not cite or quote without permission of the authors.

Flexible Working Arrangements, Collaboration, ICT and Innovation

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Preview. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Volume 30, Issue 1. Gender and firm-size: Evidence from Africa

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model. Pearson Education Limited All rights reserved.

Gender and Firm-size: Evidence from Africa

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEER TOURISM IN KENT COUNTY, MICHIGAN

Wine-Tasting by Numbers: Using Binary Logistic Regression to Reveal the Preferences of Experts

Technical Memorandum: Economic Impact of the Tutankhamun and the Golden Age of the Pharoahs Exhibition

Gasoline Empirical Analysis: Competition Bureau March 2005

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OVERALL, WE FOUND THAT:

The Contribution made by Beer to the European Economy. Poland - January 2016

The Financing and Growth of Firms in China and India: Evidence from Capital Markets

AJAE Appendix: Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Power and Priorities: Gender, Caste, and Household Bargaining in India

Fleurieu zone (other)

FACTORS DETERMINING UNITED STATES IMPORTS OF COFFEE

CHAPTER I BACKGROUND

MBA 503 Final Project Guidelines and Rubric

The Economic Impact of Wine and Grapes in Lodi 2009

Grape Growers of Ontario Developing key measures to critically look at the grape and wine industry

Preview. Introduction (cont.) Introduction. Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost

Rail Haverhill Viability Study

ECONOMIC IMPACT OF LEGALIZING RETAIL ALCOHOL SALES IN BENTON COUNTY. Produced for: Keep Dollars in Benton County

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Multiple Imputation for Missing Data in KLoSA

Recent U.S. Trade Patterns (2000-9) PP542. World Trade 1929 versus U.S. Top Trading Partners (Nov 2009) Why Do Countries Trade?

RESULTS OF THE MARKETING SURVEY ON DRINKING BEER

The Economic Impact of the Craft Brewing Industry in Maine. School of Economics Staff Paper SOE 630- February Andrew Crawley*^ and Sarah Welsh

McDONALD'S AS A MEMBER OF THE COMMUNITY

Buying Filberts On a Sample Basis

An Examination of operating costs within a state s restaurant industry

OF THE VARIOUS DECIDUOUS and

Perspective of the Labor Market for security guards in Israel in time of terror attacks

This appendix tabulates results summarized in Section IV of our paper, and also reports the results of additional tests.

How Rest Area Commercialization Will Devastate the Economic Contributions of Interstate Businesses. Acknowledgements

Emerging Local Food Systems in the Caribbean and Southern USA July 6, 2014

A Web Survey Analysis of the Subjective Well-being of Spanish Workers

The Roles of Social Media and Expert Reviews in the Market for High-End Goods: An Example Using Bordeaux and California Wines

ECONOMIC IMPACT OF WINE AND VINEYARDS IN NAPA COUNTY

To make wine, to sell the grapes or to deliver them to a cooperative: determinants of the allocation of the grapes

Internet Appendix. For. Birds of a feather: Value implications of political alignment between top management and directors

Results from the First North Carolina Wine Industry Tracker Survey

Online Appendix. for. Female Leadership and Gender Equity: Evidence from Plant Closure

Table A.1: Use of funds by frequency of ROSCA meetings in 9 research sites (Note multiple answers are allowed per respondent)


The 2006 Economic Impact of Nebraska Wineries and Grape Growers

Panel A: Treated firm matched to one control firm. t + 1 t + 2 t + 3 Total CFO Compensation 5.03% 0.84% 10.27% [0.384] [0.892] [0.

Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Notes on the Philadelphia Fed s Real-Time Data Set for Macroeconomists (RTDSM) Capacity Utilization. Last Updated: December 21, 2016

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF MODEL WINERIES IN TEXAS. Industry Report

Chapter 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

The Contribution made by Beer to the European Economy. Czech Republic - January 2016

The Market Potential for Exporting Bottled Wine to Mainland China (PRC)

1

Excise Duty on Beer and Cider and Small Breweries Relief

Harvesting Charges for Florida Citrus, 2016/17

Retailing Frozen Foods

Looking Long: Demographic Change, Economic Crisis, and the Prospects for Reducing Poverty. La Conyuntura vs. the Long-run

Decision making with incomplete information Some new developments. Rudolf Vetschera University of Vienna. Tamkang University May 15, 2017

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

A Comparison of X, Y, and Boomer Generation Wine Consumers in California

1/17/manufacturing-jobs-used-to-pay-really-well-notanymore-e/

Pasta Market in Italy to Market Size, Development, and Forecasts

Economic Contributions of the Florida Citrus Industry in and for Reduced Production

5. Supporting documents to be provided by the applicant IMPORTANT DISCLAIMER

Weekly tax table with no and half Medicare levy

Method for the imputation of the earnings variable in the Belgian LFS

Selection bias in innovation studies: A simple test

DERIVED DEMAND FOR FRESH CHEESE PRODUCTS IMPORTED INTO JAPAN

ARE THERE SKILLS PAYOFFS IN LOW AND MIDDLE-INCOME COUNTRIES?

2017 FINANCIAL REVIEW

What are the Driving Forces for Arts and Culture Related Activities in Japan?

COMPARISON OF CORE AND PEEL SAMPLING METHODS FOR DRY MATTER MEASUREMENT IN HASS AVOCADO FRUIT

Online Appendix to. Are Two heads Better Than One: Team versus Individual Play in Signaling Games. David C. Cooper and John H.

Whether to Manufacture

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF WINE AND WINE GRAPES ON THE STATE OF TEXAS 2015

International Journal of Business and Commerce Vol. 3, No.8: Apr 2014[01-10] (ISSN: )

SURVEY OF LICENSED PREMISES IN IRELAND 2009

Introduction Methods

ICC September 2018 Original: English. Emerging coffee markets: South and East Asia

ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE FLORIDA CITRUS INDUSTRY IN

Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool? Online Appendix September 2014

Online Appendix to Voluntary Disclosure and Information Asymmetry: Evidence from the 2005 Securities Offering Reform

International Trade CHAPTER 3: THE CLASSICAL WORL OF DAVID RICARDO AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE WINE AND GRAPE INDUSTRY IN CANADA 2015

UPPER MIDWEST MARKETING AREA THE BUTTER MARKET AND BEYOND

Labor Requirements and Costs for Harvesting Tomatoes. Zhengfei Guan, 1 Feng Wu, and Steven Sargent University of Florida

18 May Primary Production Select Committee Parliament Buildings Wellington

Investment Wines. - Risk Analysis. Prepared by: Michael Shortell & Adiam Woldetensae Date: 06/09/2015

Predicting Wine Quality

Sustainable Coffee Challenge FAQ

Zeitschrift für Soziologie, Jg., Heft 5, 2015, Online- Anhang

Uniform Rules Update Final EIR APPENDIX 6 ASSUMPTIONS AND CALCULATIONS USED FOR ESTIMATING TRAFFIC VOLUMES

HONDURAS. A Quick Scan on Improving the Economic Viability of Coffee Farming A QUICK SCAN ON IMPROVING THE ECONOMIC VIABILITY OF COFFEE FARMING

Paper Reference IT Principal Learning Information Technology. Level 3 Unit 2: Understanding Organisations

Transcription:

The impact of the National Minimum Wage on UK Businesses 1 Rebecca Riley and Chiara Rosazza Bondibene National Institute of Economic and Social Research 2 June 2014 Abstract This paper examines the impact of the National Minimum Wage (NMW) on a range of outcomes for low-paying companies in the UK. We distinguish between the impacts of the NMW on small and larger firms and on firms in the low-paying sectors. We examine how these effects have changed since the introduction of the NMW in 1999. We find that upon introduction the NMW increased average labour costs for low-paying companies. The NMW also raised companies' labour costs thereafter, but these increases have been more muted. We find evidence to suggest that companies may have adjusted to the increases in labour costs as a result of the NMW by raising labour productivity. Key words: minimum wage, labour costs, productivity, firm behaviour JEL codes: J08, J31, J38, L25 1 Acknowledgements and disclaimers: This work contains statistical data which is Crown Copyright; it has been made available by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) through the Secure Data Service (SDS) and has been used by permission. Neither the ONS or SDS bear any responsibility for the analysis or interpretation of the data reported here. This work uses research datasets which may not exactly reproduce National Statistics aggregates. This work was funded by the Low Pay Commission. This paper is based on an interim report for the Low Pay Commission. As such, the results reported in this paper are preliminary. Correspondence: National Institute of Economic and Social Research, 2 Dean Trench Street, Smith Square, London SW1P 3HE; Tel.: +44-207-222-7665; fax: +44-207-654-1900 E-mail: r.riley@niesr.ac.uk; c.rosazza_bondibene@niesr.ac.uk

1. Introduction This paper analyses the impact of the National Minimum Wage (NMW) on UK businesses. Business outcomes considered include labour costs, productivity, profitability and the probability of exit. Specifically, the study aims to build evidence of relevance in answering the question about how the NMW has affected the behaviour of smaller and larger firms and firms in the low paying sectors. We examine the impacts of the NMW following in broad terms the approach in Draca et al. (2005, 2011). This is a difference-in-differences approach applied in the main to firm level data. The basic idea is to look at a group of firms that were more affected by the introduction of the NMW and its subsequent up-ratings (treatment group) than a comparison set of firms (control group). By more affected we mean where wages rose by more due to the imposition of the wage floor. This quasi-experimental setting enables us to compare what happened to our outcomes of interest before and after introduction/uprating of the NMW in low wage firms to what happened to these outcomes across the same period for a comparison group of firms whose labour costs were not affected by the introduction of the NMW. The data available at this time allow us to look at the introduction of the policy in 1999 up to 2011. There is relatively little firm-level evidence on the impacts of the NMW during recession and of the NMW upratings since then. One exception is Riley and Rosazza Bondibene (2013), and our analysis here builds on this earlier analysis, which only covered the initial years since the onset of the recession in 2008. In comparison to Riley and Rosazza (2013), we make several improvements to the data analysed. First, we use postrecession data from the ARD, providing a relatively up-to-date impact analysis to 2011. Second, we exploit the longitudinal element of the ARD, making it possible to better control for changes in sample composition over time than when using the repeated cross-sections data. The use of the longitudinal data also avoids the situation where we need to define treatment and control groups based on endogenous outcomes, as in the analysis of the ARD in Riley & Rosazza Bondibene (2013). Third, we explore how one might define treatment and control groups by examining developments (over time and for different types of firm) in the link between minimum wage workers and workplace average labour costs. Finally, we derive firm-level workforce characteristics based on data for individual employees (see e.g. Haskel et al., 2005; Riley, 2010; Riley & Robinson, 2011a) which we include as additional controls in our analysis. 1

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes our research methods and section 3 discusses the data we use. Results are presented in section 4. Section 5 summarises and details our next steps. 2. Methodology To estimate the impact of the NMW on firm behaviour we follow Draca et al. (2005, 2011), Galindo-Rueda & Pereira (2004) and Riley & Rosazza Bondibene (2013) in applying a difference-in-differences estimator to firm-level data. Draca et al. (2005, 2011) look at companies in FAME to study the impact of the introduction of the NMW and very early upratings on firms profits. Galindo-Rueda & Pereira (2004) study the impact of the NMW on productivity using the Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings (ASHE) linked (by firm identifier or by sector/region) to the ARD. Riley and Rosazza Bondibene (2013) look at companies in FAME and in the ARD to look at the impact of the NMW on several indicators of firm performance, focusing not only on the introduction of the policy but also on the recent recession. Defining treatment and control groups One of the main difficulties with firm-level analysis of NMW impacts is defining a suitable set of firms to allocate to the treatment group (and the control group). We need to measure exposure to the NMW, i.e. intensity of treatment. Draca et al (2005, 2011) measure exposure to the NMW and distinguish treated from untreated firms by looking at the distribution of average labour costs (or average wages and salaries paid) per head across firms. They assume that those firms at the bottom of the distribution of average labour costs per employee are more exposed to the NMW and assign these to the treatment group. The control group is made up of firms from further up the distribution of average labour costs per employee. Importantly, they (Draca, 2011) show a correlation between average wages paid by the firm and the proportion of low-pay workers in a firm s workforce, suggesting that average wages are a means of identifying NMW exposure. Whether this is also the case for later upratings and for different size firms has not been assessed. Riley & Rosazza Bondibene (2013) use average labour costs as a means of distinguishing between treatment and control firms, inflating the cut-off between the two over time by increases in the NMW or average earnings. They apply 2

the same cut-off for all firm size groups and industries and suggest some sensitivity in estimated NMW impacts to the cut-off chosen. Here we further explore how one might define treatment and control groups, when analysing the impacts of the NMW on business outcomes. We examine the link between minimum wage workers and workplace average labour costs as in Draca et al. (2011), but using three cross sections of WERS (1998, 2004 and 2011). This allows us to assess whether the distribution of NMW workers across firms has changed over time and hence whether alternative cut-offs to define treatment firms and control firms are necessary for later upratings. We look at the concentration of NMW workers across the distribution of firms' average labour costs separately for different size firm and for the low pay industries. This tells us whether the selection of treatment and control groups used to identify NMW effects in the business population can also be used to identify NMW effects within these sub-groups of firms. We also examine these issues using the ASHE linked to the ARD to check whether employees that are paid the NMW, which may differ from employees with low observed weekly wages (because individuals may work less than full time), tend to locate in companies with low average labour costs. Here we cannot generate a measure of NMW workers per firm because the ASHE is but a 1% sample of employees. Instead we look at the distribution of average labour costs for two groups of workers: employees paid the NMW and employees paid more than the NMW. If the distribution of employer average labour costs across NMW workers lies significantly to the left of the distribution of employer average labour costs across workers that are paid more than the NMW, then this further validates the use of firm average labour costs as a means of distinguishing between treatment and control firms. Longitudinal panel model Informed by the analysis of the NMW and labour costs we select firms for the treatment and control groups based on their characteristics in the year prior to the recession or introduction of the NMW. Our main interest is in NMW impacts since recession, but we include the introduction for comparison and validation of the treatment and control allocation. We then track outcomes for these two groups of firms three and four years later, comparing the difference in performance between these two groups to the difference in performance before. We estimate this on a balanced panel of firms. 3

More formally we estimate the impact of the NMW in a standard difference-indifferences framework as shown in equation (1), where p=0 refers to the period before the introduction of the NMW and p=1 refers to the period after the introduction/uprating of the NMW. (1) In this set-up is the outcome of interest for firm i at time t. is a dummy variable equal to one if the firm is in the treatment group and zero otherwise. is a dummy variable equal to one if p=1, i.e. if the NMW is in place, and zero otherwise. The are controls for firm characteristics intended to net out differences between firms unrelated to the NMW. is an error term and the rest are parameters to be estimated. In this example measures the impact of the introduction of the NMW on outcome. In order to evaluate the more recent impacts of the NMW we could in principle estimate equation (1) over a longer time period, tracking outcomes for the cohort of companies selected in the year prior to introduction of the NMW over this longer period. But, this raises a number of issues. First, as time progresses firms may move out of the treatment and control groups (they may also do this in the first three and four years following introduction, but this is less likely over a shorter time span), so that the treatment and comparison groups become less suitable for identifying NMW effects in the later years of the policy. Second, firms may move out of their size category, which matters because we wish to distinguish between policy effects on smaller and larger firms. Third, sample sizes become small in more recent years because an increasing proportion of the cohort of firms exits the market and the remaining group of companies becomes arguably less representative of the group of firms that are affected by the policy. For these reasons we evaluate the later impacts of the NMW by estimating equation (1) for a new set of firms. Using the thresholds for average labour costs identified in the analysis discussed in the previous section we select firms for the treatment and comparison groups based on their characteristics in some year after the NMW was already in place. For example, we select firms on the basis of their average labour costs in the year before the recession hit. We then track these firms over the course of the three and four years since recession (p=1) and compare these outcomes to those in the three and four years before recession (p=0). In this model in equation (1) measures 4

the impact of the upratings in the NMW since the recession on outcome conditional on the existence of a wage floor (because the NMW policy is in place in both the preand post-policy periods). For this interpretation to be valid we are assuming that the policy effects of a given wage floor are the same in recession as in a period of stable economic growth. An alternative interpretation is that in equation (1) measures the difference between the impact of a given wage floor during a period of slow economic growth and its impact in a period of stable economic growth. Increases in the NMW since recession have been very muted, and hence this latter interpretation seems quite reasonable. Ideally, using this approach it would be useful to carry out falsification tests by estimating equation (1) during a period before the introduction of the NMW, i.e. a period where both p=0 and p=1 refer to a time before the introduction of the NMW (1994-1998, when there was no NMW and there were no Wage Councils). Using the same thresholds for average labour costs, adjusted for changes over time in average earnings, we would then select firms for the treatment and comparison groups based on their characteristics in the year before a "fictive" policy intervention. is then a dummy variable equal to one if the "fictive" policy intervention is in place, and zero otherwise. Then would measure the impact of the pretend policy on outcome, and we would expect it to equal zero if we are to have any confidence in the identification strategy. This falsification test is not possible with the ARD, which is only available from 1998. However, the analysis in Riley & Rosazza Bondibene (2013) demonstrated the validity of the approach we take here using FAME. Outcome measures examined include total labour costs per head; labour productivity; profitability (measured as the ratio of gross profits to value added to proxy price-cost margins as in Draca et al. (2005, 2011) and Forth et al. (2009)); we plan to examine probability of exit (business failure) in a similar approach. In this paper we also examine firms' employment. 3. Data Annual Respondents Database The Annual Respondents Database (ARD) is an establishment level business survey (or set of surveys) conducted by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) that is widely used 5

in the study of firm behaviour and productivity analysis. The ARD has previously been used to study the impacts of the NMW on plant-level productivity, profitability and exit by Forth et al. (2009). They use data 1999-2006 and do not use a difference-indifferences approach. Galindo-Rueda & Pereira (2004) use the ARD to study the impact of the introduction of the NMW on productivity, employment and unit labour costs, using a difference-in-differences approach on data 1997-2001. Neither of these studies identifies exposure to the NMW using average labour costs (wages) as we do in this study. The only study which uses the ARD and a similar identification strategy to evaluate the impact of the NMW on businesses is Riley and Rosazza Bondibene (2013). However, unlike our previous use of the ARD, we now exploit the longitudinal element of the survey. This means we are better able to control for changes in sample composition over time than before. The ARD holds information on the nature of production in British businesses and is essentially a census of larger businesses and a stratified (by industry, region and employment size) random sample of businesses with less than 250 employees (SMEs). It covers businesses in the non-financial non-agriculture market sectors. 2 Data are available for 1997-2011 and for manufacturing back to 1974 and are collected for establishments (or rather, reporting units). We undertake our analysis at the level of the enterprise, which corresponds to the smallest legal unit in the ARD and hence the smallest unit with a decision making capacity. Also our study focuses on the period from 1998 to 2011 when most of the two-digit SIC categories are avaliable, including the service industries which include the main low pay sectors. The sampling frame is the Inter-Departmental Business Register (IDBR), a list of all UK incorporated businesses and other businesses registered for tax purposes (employee or sales taxes). The ARD includes basic information (e.g. industry, ownership structure, and indicative employment 3 ) for all businesses in the sampling frame. In the sectors that we 2 The ARD includes partial coverage of the agricultural sector (we exclude these businesses) as well as businesses in "non-market" service sectors such as education, health and social work. We exclude businesses in these latter sectors where inputs and outputs are thought not to be directly comparable, making productivity analysis difficult to undertake. We also exclude businesses in the mining and quarrying, and utilities sectors (typically very large businesses with erratic patterns of output) and in the real estate sector, where output mostly reflects imputed housing rents. 3 Indicative employment information is collected from a variety of sources and is sometimes imputed from turnover. We use this indicative measure of employment as our measure of employment for nonsurveyed as well as for surveyed businesses as we do not have a consistent series of year average or point in time employment estimates for surveyed businesses. For those years where we are able to make the 6

consider this population includes more than 1.5 million businesses covering employment of just under 16 million, a little less than three fifths the number employed in the British economy as a whole. The population data allow us to determine business exit, which cannot be calculated from the surveyed sample alone (Disney et al., 2003) and also allows us to calculate grossing weights that we apply in some specifications of our analysis as a robustness check. Sampling probabilities in the ARD vary by size of firm. In particular, the probability of observing in the survey a specific micro business (a business employing less than 10 employees) in a specific year is just 1%. As a result, the probability of observing a micro business in two separate years (conditional on being live) is only 1 in 10,000. 4 Typically we observe only 60 continuing micro firms, which represents 0.01% of the population of continuing micro firms. Following our calculations micro businesses account for a sizable share of economic activity in Britain: 90% of businesses in the sectors we consider are micro businesses and these account for 20% of employed persons there. But, the longitudinal sample is insufficient to support representative analysis of this group of firms and therefore we drop them from our analysis and focus on the sample of firms with 10 or more employees. Our proxies for our outcomes of interest using the ARD are 5 : Average wages: total labour cost 6 /employment Labour productivity: GVA at factor costs/employment comparison this indicative employment measure corresponds very closely with the point in time measure of employment that we observe for surveyed businesses, except in the earlier years of the survey where there is some discrepancy. 4 This applies when there is a minimum of three years between surveys. When there are three years or less between survey years the longitudinal sampling probability should be closer to zero. This is because once selected for the survey in year t a micro firm cannot be selected for a repeat survey before year t+4 unless it changes size category. These (Osmotherly) rules are intended to reduce the burden on small businesses (Bovill, 2012). 5 We truncate the top and the bottom 1% of the labour productivity and total labour costs distribution within 1-digit industry sectors in each annual survey. We also make use of the longitudinal data to eliminate further outlying observations. 6 This represents amounts paid during the year to employees. This includes all overtime payments, bonuses, commissions, payments in kind, benefits in kind, holiday pay, employer s national insurance contributions, payments into pension funds by employers and redundancy payments less any amount reimbursed for this purpose from government sources. No deduction is made for income tax or employee s national insurance contributions etc. Payment to working proprietors, travelling expenses, lodging allowances, etc are excluded (ABI, Background Information, Archive Data). 7

Price to cost margins: (GVA at factor costs total labour costs)/ GVA at factor costs The ABI financial information is published in current values. GVA deflators published by the ONS are used to construct real labour productivity values; these are available at the 2- and sometimes the 3-digit sector level. 7 They are also used to construct a measure of real producer wages. Separately we deflate average labour costs with the average earnings index, benchmarking low pay against average wages in the economy. Other data We link the Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings (ASHE) by firm identifier to the ARD in order to evaluate the distribution of average labour costs across different types of employees. We also use the ASHE to construct additional control variables, which are then linked onto firms in the ARD via industry, firm size and by whether the firm is low paying or not 8 (rather than by firm identifier). These controls include the proportion of female workers and average weekly hours of work (basic paid hours and paid overtime hours as defined in ASHE). We also compute the proportion of workers that are in highly skilled occupations. The occupations are classified based on a study by Elias and Purcell (2004) who develop a measure of highly qualified labour within the UK labour market, SOC(HE) 9. 4. Results Defining treatment and control groups In Figures 1-3 we plot the proportion of workers paid the NMW against the establishment's average annual wage for each cross-section of WERS. The y-axis shows the proportion of workers paid below the minimum wage in the establishment 7 Before 2008 industry was coded to the UK Standard Industrial Classification 2003. From 2008 onwards this changed to the UK Standard Industrial Classification 2007. To maintain continuity in the sectors that we analyse this requires us to drop a few 3-digit sectors. 8 We aggregate SIC2007 industries at section level, except for the manufacturing sector where we aggregate at 1-digit level. We are also able to distinguish between SMEs and large firms. To define low paying firms we apply the same thresholds used in our diff-in-diff analysis, based on ARD firm total labour costs. The minimum sample size for each cell is 30 firms. 9 The measure they develop, SOC(HE), is based on SOC2000 and SOC1990 codes. In line with their study we proxy highly skilled occupations as those that they classify as: 1. Traditional graduate occupations; 2. Modern graduate occupations; 3. New graduate occupations. 8

(respectively 3.60 per hour in 1998; 5.05 per hour in 2004; 6.19 in 2011). The x-axis shows the average annual wage at the workplace. This is divided in bins for 5 percentiles from lowest (left) to highest (right). We mark thresholds used in our previous analysis ( 8,000; 10,000 and 12,000) with vertical lines 10. These figures suggest that minimum wage workers are concentrated in firms that pay low average wages and that this pattern has persisted over time. Furthermore, the concentration of minimum wage workers in workplaces that pay low average wages is evident within SMEs, larger companies, and amongst firms in LPC low pay sectors (see Figures 4-7 for 1998 and Figures A1-A7 in the Appendix for 2004 and 2011). Moreover, these figures suggest that the thresholds used to distinguish treatment from control firms in our previous analysis are reasonable. There is not one clear threshold for the analysis, suggesting that there is merit in applying different cut-offs to test the robustness of the results. One important thing to notice is that although the concentration of low pay workers amongst low paying firms is evident for the economy as a whole (Figure 1) and amongst firms in LPC low pay sectors (Figure 4), there is a striking difference between these two distributions. Our WERS analysis shows that the great majority of the firms in the low pay sectors have a high concentration of low pay workers (perhaps by definition!). This makes it more difficult to find a suitable control group for detecting NMW impacts amongst firms in the low pay sectors. In other words, almost all firms in the low pay sectors are affected by the NMW, therefore the treated are being compared with a control group of firms which still have a relatively high proportion of low pay workers. Thus our methodology is likely to underestimate the impact of the NMW on wages in these sectors. One alternative for consideration is to select a control group of firms from another industry, but this is not ideal if there are industry specific trends. Figures 8-19 use the ASHE linked to the ARD to show the distribution of average enterprise labour costs (deflated to 1998 values by annual changes in the National Minimum Wage) for two groups: employees paid at or below the minimum wage rate (blue line) and employees paid above the minimum wage rate (red line). For each of these figures we do a Komolgorov-Smirnov tests (not shown) which suggests that the distributions of average enterprise labour costs are different for these two groups of employees. In line with the WERS analysis, these figures confirm that workers paid at or 10 In 2004 and 2011 we adjust the thresholds ( 8,000, 10,000 and 12,000) by the percentage increase of the NMW from the introduction to the year of analysis. 9

below the NMW are concentrated in establishments with low average labour costs. This pattern again seems to persists over time and is evident within SMEs, larger companies, amongst LPC low pay sectors and other market sectors. We also do probit regressions looking at the probability of being an employee paid at or below the minimum wage (not shown). We find a statistically significant negative association between average enterprise labour costs and the probability of being a minimum wage worker. In other words, if a person works in an enterprise that pays its employees on average a low wage, then it is more likely that this person is paid at or below the NMW. We also find that this relationship is more negative and statistically significant for employees in low pay sectors. Performance differences between treatment and control firms In Tables 1-6 we estimate equation (1) for the following year pairs: (1998, 2001), (1998, 2002); (2002, 2006), (2002, 2007); (2007, 2010), (2007, 2011). For each pair the first year refers to time p=0 in equation (1) and the last year refers to time p=1. Because the composition of the longitudinal panel can vary substantially across year pairs, one of our robustness criteria is that findings are replicated (qualitatively) on both the 3 year and 4 year differences. A second robustness criteria is that findings are replicated (qualitatively) for different cut-offs used to distinguish between the treatment and control groups. We use cut-offs 8,000, 10,000 and 12,000, which in 2008 prices correspond to the thresholds indicated in the Tables (i.e. 12,000; 15,000 and 18,000). A third sensitivity test is that we expect results to hold both using OLS and Robust Regression. As a final robustness check, we show specifications which only include 2-digit industry controls and specifications which include additional time-varying controls. In the analysis we focus not only on all firms but we also differentiate by size (i.e. SMEs and larger companies), and by LPC low pay sectors and other market sectors. Sample sizes for each of these specifications are reported in Tables B1-B3 in the Appendix. Labour costs In Tables 1 and 2 we show that at the introduction of the policy average labour costs increased more amongst our treatment group of low pay firms than amongst firms that paid better wages. This pattern is evident on both 3 and 4 year differences and within SMEs, larger companies, amongst LPC low pay sectors and other market sectors. This 10

lends some credibility to the identification strategy used to examine NMW impacts, which basically attributes the difference in changes in outcomes over time between lower and higher average labour cost businesses to the NMW. Although we include several controls in the analysis, it is important to bear in mind that there could be other influences on business outcomes over time that affect more and less low pay companies differently. When we are unable to take these into account in the analysis these can bias our estimates of NMW impacts. It is also important to be aware that we cannot directly compare the magnitudes of these impact estimates for the Low Pay Sectors (and SMEs in the Low Pay Sectors) with that for other sectors since the impact of the NMW for firms in the low pay industries is likely to be underestimated. The reasons for this are explained in the previous section. From Table 3 to Table 6 we focus on the pair of years after the introduction, specifically, (2002, 2006), (2002, 2007) and (2007, 2010), (2007, 2011). We generally again find that average labour costs per head increased amongst low pay firms (the treatment group) compared to less low pay firms (the control group). This is evident for SMEs and large firms, for firms in LPC low pay sectors and for firms in other market sectors. As expected, the magnitude of these average labour cost effects is generally greatest upon introduction of the NMW and smallest during the recession. This is in line with changes in the NMW over time, and gives us some confidence that the treatment and control firms are selected appropriately. Other outcomes We also estimate the difference in 3- and 4-year changes in labour productivity (GVA per head), employment and profit margins between lower and higher average labour cost businesses, using the same methodology described above. The impact estimates in tables 1 and 2 suggest that the increases in labour costs associated with the introduction of the NMW were also associated with increases in labour productivity. This finding is relatively robust, apparent across all the subsets of companies shown, all thresholds used to define treatment and control groups, whether we look at 3 or 4 year changes, using robust regression, and including additional controls (Table 2). We find some negative and significant employment coefficients, but these are not consistent across the specifications shown and usually disappear when we use robust regression. We do not find any robust evidence of impacts on profit margins. 11

Tables 3-7, which show impact estimates for later time periods, suggest that labour cost increases in low paying firms 2002-2005/6 and spanning the recession 2007-2010/11 were associated with increases in labour productivity. But these increases, like the increases in labour costs, were typically more muted during these later periods (in most specifications) and are not evident in all specifications. We find no robust evidence to suggest there was any impact of the NMW on employment or profit margins, in aggregate or for the sub-groups of firms that we consider. 5. Summary and next steps To summarise, this paper makes several improvements to our previous study on the impact of the NMW on UK companies (Riley and Rosazza Bondibene, 2013). First, we use post-recession data from the ARD, providing a relatively up-to-date impact analysis to 2011. Second, we exploit the longitudinal element of the ARD, being better able to control for changes in sample composition over time than before. Third, we explore how one might define treatment and control groups by examining developments (over time and for different types of firm) in the link between minimum wage workers and workplace average labour costs, using both three cross sections of WERS (1998, 2004 and 2011) and the ASHE linked to the ARD. Finally, we derive firm-level workforce characteristics based on data for individual employees (see e.g. Haskel et al., 2005; Riley, 2010; Riley & Robinson, 2011a) which we include as additional controls in our analysis. Our results from analysing WERS and ASHE linked to the ARD validate the difference-indifferences methodology used here, but also point to difficulties in making direct comparisons of the magnitudes of NMW impact estimates across the low pay industries and other industries. Analysing the ARD we do not find robust evidence to suggest that trends in profit margins differed substantially between lower and higher average labour cost businesses over any of the periods analysed. We do find some evidence to suggest that GVA per head increased amongst low pay firms compared to firms with higher average labour costs. This is particularly evident upon the introduction of the NMW and is less clear during later periods. 12

Taking this research forward we aim to further extend our analysis to examine whether labour productivity changes brought about via the NMW came about through changes in the amount of capital used per employee or through better training of the work force and/or better motivated employees (efficiency wage type effects). If these latter effects are important they would result in improvements in total factor productivity (TFP). 13

Bibliography Dickens, R., Riley, R. and Wilkinson, D. (2009) The employment and hours of work effects of the National Minimum Wage, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Dickens, R., Riley, R. and Wilkinson, D. (2012). Re-examining the impact of the National Minimum Wage on earnings, employment and hours: The importance of recession and firm-size, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Dickens, R., Riley, R. and Wilkinson, D. (forthcoming). A re-examination of the impact of the National Minimum Wage on employment, Economica. Dolton, P. and Rosazza Bondibene, C. (2012) 'An Evaluation of the International Experience of Minimum Wages in an Economic Downturn, Economic Policy, 69: 99-142 Draca, M., Machin, S., and Van Reenen, J. (2005) The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Profits and Prices, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Draca, M., Machin, S., and Van Reenen, J. (2011) Minimum Wages and Firm Profitability, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3, 129-151. Elias, P. and Purcell, K. (2004) SOC(HE): a Classification of Occupations for Studying the Graduate Labour Market, Research Graduate Careers Seven Years On, Research paper n. 6. Forth, J., Rincon-Aznar, A., Robinson, C. and Harris, R. (2009) The Impact of Recent Upratings of the National Minimum Wage on Competitiveness, Business Performance and Sector Dynamics, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Galindo-Rueda, F. and Pereira, S. (2004) The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on British Firms, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Griffith, R. (1999). Using the ARD establishment level data to look at foreign ownership and productivity in the United Kingdom, The Economic Journal, Vol. 109, No. 456, pp. F416-F442. Harris, R.I.D. (2005) Economics of the Workplace: Special Issue Editorial, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52(3), 323-343. Haskel, J., Hawkes, D., and Pereira, S. (2005) Skills, human capital and the plant productivity gap: UK evidence from matched plant, worker and workforce data, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5334. Riley, R. (2010) Industry knowledge spillovers: Do workers gain from their collective experience?, National Institute Discussion Paper No. 353. Riley, R. and Robinson, C. (2011) UK Economic Performance: How Far do Intangibles Count?, FP7 Innodrive Working Paper No 14. Riley, R. and Rosazza Bondibene, C. (2013) The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Firm Behaviour during Recession, Report to the Low Pay Commission. 14

Rizov, M., and Croucher, R. (2011) The impact of the UK national minimum wage on productivity by low-paying sectors and firm-size groups, Research Report for the Low Pay Commission. Stewart, M. (2004a) The Impact of the Introduction of the UK Minimum Wage on the Employment Probabilities of Low Wage Workers, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 67-97. Stewart, M. (2004b) The Employment Effects of the National Minimum Wage, Economic Journal, 114, C110-C116. Stewart, M. and J. Swaffield (2008) The other margin: do minimum wages cause working hours adjustments for low-wage workers? Economica, 75, 148-167. 15

Figure 1. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS1998).6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 1998. Authors calculations Figure 2. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS2004).6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 2004. Authors calculations. 16

Figure 3. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS2011).6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 2011. Authors calculations. Figure 4. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS1998) only for low pay industries..6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 1998. Authors calculations. Note: we use the Low Pay Commission definition of Low Pay Industries. These include: retail, hospitability, social care, food processing, leisure, travel and sport, cleaning, security, textile and clothing, hairdressing. 17

Figure 5. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS1998) only for small size establishments..6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 1998. Authors calculations. Note: we define small size establishments as establishments with less than 50 employees. Figure 6. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS1998) only for medium size establishments..6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 1998. Authors calculations. Note: we define medium size establishments as establishments with employment between 50 and 249. 18

Figure 7. Comparison of proportion of low pay workers and establishment average wages at the introduction of the NMW (WERS1998) only for large size establishments..6.5.4.3.2.1 0 Source: WERS 1998. Authors calculations. Note: we define large size establishments as establishments with more than 249 employees. 19

0.02.04.06.08.1 0.02.04.06.08 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 8. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 1998, SMEs 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define SMEs as firms with less than 250 employees. Figure 9. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 1998, employees in large firms 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define large size firms as firms with more than 249 employees. 20

0.05.1.15.2 0.02.04.06.08 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 10. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2002, SMEs 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define SMEs as firms with less than 250 employees. Figure 11. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2002, employees in large firms 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define large size firms as firms with more than 249 employees. 21

0.05.1.15.2 0.02.04.06.08 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 12. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2006, SMEs 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define SMEs as firms with less than 250 employees. Figure 13. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2006, employees in large firms 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define large size firms as firms with more than 249 employees. 22

0.05.1.15.2 0.02.04.06.08 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 14. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2010, SMEs 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define SMEs as firms with less than 250 employees. Figure 15. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2010, employees in large firms 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we define large size firms as firms with more than 249 employees. 23

0.02.04.06.08 0.05.1.15 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 16. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 1998, Low pay industries 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we use the Low Pay Commission definition of Low Pay Industries. These include: retail, hospitability, social care, food processing, leisure, travel and sport, cleaning, security, textile and clothing, hairdressing. Figure 17. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 1998, Other industries 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. 24

0.02.04.06.08.1 0.05.1.15.2 THE IMPACT OF THE NATIONAL MINIMUM WAGE ON UK BUSINESSES Figure 18. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2010, Low pay industries 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. Note: we use the Low Pay Commission definition of Low Pay Industries. These include: retail, hospitability, social care, food processing, leisure, travel and sport, cleaning, security, textile and clothing, hairdressing. Figure 19. Distribution of large employer average labour costs amongst low paid and other employees 2010, Other industries 0 10 20 30 40 50 average labour costs Source: ASHE linked to ARD. Authors' calculations. 25

Table 1. Longitudinal panel models using the ARD. Control for SIC2007 2-digit industries. 1998-2001/2002. 1998-2001 1998-2002 OLS Robust Regression OLS Robust Regression threshold 2008 prices 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 All average labour costs (w) 0.126 *** 0.124 *** 0.111 *** 0.092 *** 0.097 *** 0.087 *** 0.122 *** 0.119 *** 0.127 *** 0.089 *** 0.088 *** 0.101 *** average labour costs (p) 0.112 *** 0.108 *** 0.092 *** 0.085 *** 0.085 *** 0.070 *** 0.096 *** 0.097 *** 0.104 *** 0.074 *** 0.073 *** 0.082 *** GVA per head 0.119 *** 0.112 *** 0.109 *** 0.127 *** 0.100 *** 0.090 *** 0.075 *** 0.076 *** 0.106 *** 0.082 ** 0.084 *** 0.104 *** employment -0.023-0.048 *** -0.056 *** 0.005-0.026-0.039 0.016 0.009-0.015 0.015 0.003-0.021 profit margins -0.004-0.002 0.023 0.005 0.009 0.009 0.018 0.013 0.038-0.014-0.012-0.003 Not Low Pay average labour costs (w) 0.187 *** 0.192 *** 0.167 *** 0.173 *** 0.196 *** 0.167 *** 0.195 *** 0.201 *** 0.213 *** 0.143 *** 0.151 *** 0.190 *** sectors average labour costs (p) 0.164 *** 0.164 *** 0.132 *** 0.160 *** 0.170 *** 0.132 *** 0.151 *** 0.158 *** 0.169 *** 0.110 *** 0.115 *** 0.151 *** GVA per head 0.157 *** 0.168 *** 0.128 *** 0.158 ** 0.135 *** 0.111 *** 0.152 *** 0.164 *** 0.172 *** 0.120 ** 0.136 *** 0.152 *** employment -0.079-0.156 *** -0.131 *** -0.061-0.118-0.095 0.027-0.070 * -0.097 *** 0.014-0.068-0.094 profit margins -0.003 0.008 0.001-0.018-0.003-0.012 0.102 0.064 0.050-0.026 0.000-0.004 Low Pay average labour costs (w) 0.146 *** 0.130 *** 0.107 *** 0.120 *** 0.099 *** 0.074 *** 0.143 *** 0.121 *** 0.107 *** 0.129 *** 0.103 *** 0.085 *** sectors average labour costs (p) 0.119 *** 0.102 *** 0.077 *** 0.096 *** 0.074 *** 0.047 ** 0.104 *** 0.084 *** 0.069 *** 0.095 *** 0.069 *** 0.051 ** GVA per head 0.110 *** 0.072 *** 0.090 *** 0.124 *** 0.079 ** 0.073 ** 0.071 ** 0.037 0.063 ** 0.092 ** 0.065 * 0.070 ** employment -0.085 *** -0.088 *** -0.087 *** -0.043-0.067-0.080-0.067 ** -0.049 ** -0.054 ** -0.057-0.064-0.069 profit margins -0.033-0.049 * 0.012 0.003 0.003 0.017-0.014-0.027 0.022-0.007-0.021-0.003 SMEs average labour costs (w) 0.130 *** 0.122 *** 0.114 *** 0.093 *** 0.103 *** 0.094 *** 0.150 *** 0.139 *** 0.157 *** 0.087 *** 0.093 *** 0.127 *** average labour costs (p) 0.118 *** 0.105 *** 0.093 *** 0.093 *** 0.088 *** 0.074 *** 0.126 *** 0.117 *** 0.134 *** 0.073 *** 0.075 *** 0.105 *** GVA per head 0.133 *** 0.107 *** 0.094 *** 0.150 *** 0.103 *** 0.080 *** 0.135 *** 0.102 *** 0.126 *** 0.105 ** 0.094 *** 0.118 *** employment -0.056 * -0.063 *** -0.073 *** -0.033-0.049-0.064 0.014-0.002-0.048 *** 0.017 0.005-0.039 profit margins 0.009 0.008 0.014 0.009 0.004-0.003 0.136 0.079 0.059-0.006-0.018-0.012 Large average labour costs (w) 0.124 *** 0.124 *** 0.104 *** 0.090 *** 0.092 *** 0.077 *** 0.102 *** 0.097 *** 0.087 *** 0.104 *** 0.087 *** 0.075 *** average labour costs (p) 0.107 *** 0.112 *** 0.088 *** 0.076 *** 0.083 *** 0.065 *** 0.074 *** 0.076 *** 0.065 *** 0.081 *** 0.074 *** 0.061 *** GVA per head 0.096 *** 0.115 *** 0.125 *** 0.099 ** 0.095 *** 0.096 *** 0.020 0.051 * 0.081 *** 0.064 0.080 ** 0.093 *** employment -0.023-0.030-0.023 0.003-0.031-0.024-0.024 0.009 0.021-0.013-0.023 0.003 profit margins -0.027-0.018 0.031-0.002 0.014 0.023-0.091 ** -0.055 * 0.016-0.021-0.002 0.007 SMEs in average labour costs (w) 0.166 *** 0.129 *** 0.103 *** 0.139 *** 0.109 *** 0.076 ** 0.177 *** 0.141 *** 0.138 *** 0.141 *** 0.098 *** 0.096 *** Low Pay average labour costs (p) 0.138 *** 0.098 *** 0.070 *** 0.115 *** 0.079 ** 0.045 0.137 *** 0.101 *** 0.096 *** 0.104 *** 0.058 * 0.055 * sectors GVA per head 0.154 *** 0.080 * 0.079 ** 0.166 *** 0.096 * 0.072 0.145 *** 0.065 0.098 *** 0.132 ** 0.073 0.090 * employment -0.096 ** -0.112 *** -0.125 *** -0.068-0.094-0.113-0.007-0.016-0.040-0.012-0.024-0.041 profit margins -0.007-0.032 0.004 0.007 0.004 0.008 0.112 0.049 0.070-0.002-0.029-0.015 Source: ARD, 1998-2011. Notes: *** Significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level.

Table 2. Longitudinal panel models using the ARD. Control for SIC2007 2-digit industries, proportion of part-time workers, proportion of workers in highly skilled occupations, average total paid weekly hours. 1998-2001/2002. 1998-2001 OLS Robust Regression OLS Robust Regression threshold 2008 prices 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 All average labour costs (w) 0.124 *** 0.123 *** 0.111 *** 0.086 *** 0.094 *** 0.087 *** 0.125 *** 0.120 *** 0.128 *** 0.087 *** 0.084 *** 0.098 *** average labour costs (p) 0.109 *** 0.108 *** 0.093 *** 0.080 *** 0.083 *** 0.070 *** 0.098 *** 0.098 *** 0.105 *** 0.071 *** 0.068 *** 0.079 *** GVA per head 0.122 *** 0.113 *** 0.108 *** 0.130 *** 0.099 *** 0.089 *** 0.082 *** 0.078 *** 0.105 *** 0.088 *** 0.082 *** 0.101 *** employment -0.176 *** -0.129 *** -0.112 *** -0.161 * -0.093-0.069 0.033 0.067 *** 0.041 ** 0.043 0.061 0.044 profit margins -0.003-0.004 0.020 0.007 0.009 0.007 0.030 0.018 0.039-0.013-0.013-0.005 Not Low Pay average labour costs (w) 0.185 *** 0.195 *** 0.170 *** 0.163 *** 0.200 *** 0.171 *** 0.196 *** 0.205 *** 0.217 *** 0.140 *** 0.149 *** 0.193 *** sectors average labour costs (p) 0.162 *** 0.167 *** 0.134 *** 0.147 *** 0.173 *** 0.135 *** 0.151 *** 0.162 *** 0.174 *** 0.108 *** 0.112 *** 0.155 *** GVA per head 0.155 *** 0.169 *** 0.126 *** 0.160 *** 0.138 *** 0.112 *** 0.150 ** 0.166 *** 0.172 *** 0.118 * 0.136 *** 0.153 *** employment -0.161 * -0.182 *** -0.152 *** -0.263-0.165-0.086-0.030 0.004-0.041-0.054 0.001-0.007 profit margins -0.009 0.002-0.005-0.016-0.004-0.014 0.098 0.061 0.045-0.028-0.002-0.005 Low Pay average labour costs (w) 0.146 *** 0.127 *** 0.097 *** 0.130 *** 0.099 *** 0.066 *** 0.151 *** 0.123 *** 0.104 *** 0.128 *** 0.096 *** 0.074 *** sectors average labour costs (p) 0.119 *** 0.098 *** 0.067 *** 0.106 *** 0.073 *** 0.038 * 0.109 *** 0.083 *** 0.063 *** 0.092 *** 0.059 *** 0.035 GVA per head 0.122 *** 0.079 *** 0.088 *** 0.141 *** 0.087 ** 0.071 ** 0.086 ** 0.038 0.054 * 0.111 *** 0.062 * 0.058 employment -0.458 *** -0.416 *** -0.400 *** -0.369 *** -0.350 *** -0.334 *** -0.232 *** -0.170 *** -0.148 *** -0.124-0.119-0.080 profit margins -0.030-0.043 0.013 0.011 0.007 0.022 0.012-0.009 0.031-0.004-0.020-0.004 SMEs average labour costs (w) 0.140 *** 0.141 *** 0.129 *** 0.096 *** 0.118 *** 0.107 *** 0.143 *** 0.143 *** 0.161 *** 0.074 *** 0.100 *** 0.135 *** average labour costs (p) 0.118 *** 0.114 *** 0.101 *** 0.089 *** 0.092 *** 0.080 *** 0.102 *** 0.110 *** 0.132 *** 0.040 0.063 *** 0.107 *** GVA per head 0.124 *** 0.116 *** 0.099 *** 0.146 *** 0.114 *** 0.087 *** 0.118 ** 0.094 *** 0.124 *** 0.077 0.082 ** 0.116 *** employment -0.077 * -0.096 *** -0.105 *** -0.042-0.079-0.091 * 0.039-0.016-0.072 *** 0.052-0.004-0.059 profit margins -0.003 0.006 0.012 0.010 0.006-0.006 0.169 0.086 0.060-0.003-0.017-0.011 Large average labour costs (w) 0.132 *** 0.149 *** 0.126 *** 0.090 *** 0.105 *** 0.085 *** 0.134 *** 0.137 *** 0.122 *** 0.121 *** 0.114 *** 0.097 *** average labour costs (p) 0.115 *** 0.141 *** 0.116 *** 0.074 *** 0.099 *** 0.078 *** 0.107 *** 0.121 *** 0.107 *** 0.104 *** 0.107 *** 0.091 *** GVA per head 0.109 *** 0.137 *** 0.142 *** 0.106 ** 0.113 *** 0.099 *** 0.049 0.085 *** 0.106 *** 0.086 * 0.108 *** 0.106 *** employment -0.017-0.018-0.002 0.001-0.041-0.024-0.018 0.023 0.046-0.021-0.040-0.006 profit margins -0.021-0.024 0.022 0.000 0.008 0.012-0.093 ** -0.067 ** -0.001-0.021-0.013-0.007 SMEs in average labour costs (w) 0.181 *** 0.141 *** 0.116 *** 0.141 *** 0.112 *** 0.082 ** 0.165 *** 0.126 *** 0.117 *** 0.130 *** 0.093 *** 0.081 *** Low Pay average labour costs (p) 0.148 *** 0.106 *** 0.079 *** 0.114 *** 0.076 ** 0.047 0.092 *** 0.057 ** 0.047 * 0.058 0.021 0.012 sectors GVA per head 0.152 ** 0.115 ** 0.110 ** 0.157 ** 0.129 ** 0.100 * 0.119 * 0.025 0.047 0.108 0.027 0.033 employment -0.164 ** -0.169 *** -0.155 *** -0.117-0.121-0.119 0.038-0.051-0.093 ** 0.043-0.051-0.078 profit margins -0.015-0.018 0.016 0.011 0.030 0.026 0.174 0.075 0.087 0.012-0.025-0.012 Source: ARD, 1998-2011. Notes: *** Significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level. 1998-2002 1